American Economic Association

Report 3 Downloads 71 Views
American Economic Association Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity Author(s): Steven N. Kaplan and Per Strömberg Source: The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 23, No. 1 (Winter, 2009), pp. 121-146 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/27648297 Accessed: 18-08-2015 18:29 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/ info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Journal of Economic Perspectives.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives?Volume

23, Number 1?Winter 2009?Pages

121-146

Buyouts and Private Equity

Leveraged

Steven N. Kaplan

and Per Str?mberg

a leveraged buyout, a company is acquired by a specialized investment firm a relatively large portion of using a relatively small portion of equity and outside debt financing. The leveraged buyout investment firms today refer to

In

(and are generally referred to) as private equity firms. In a typical an leveraged buyout transaction, the private equity firm buys majority control of existing or mature firm. This arrangement isdistinct from venture capital firms that themselves

or emerging companies, and typically do not obtain typically invest in young In this control. paper, we focus specifically on private equity firms and the majority in which they invest, and we will use the terms private equity and leveraged buyouts leveraged buyout

interchangeably. buyouts first emerged

Leveraged 1980s. As leveraged predicted dominant

as an

activity increased

important phenomenon in that decade, Jensen

in the

(1989) buyout that the leveraged buyout organizations would eventually become the form. He argued that the private equity firm corporate organizational

itself combined

stakes in its portfolio companies, ownership for the private equity firm professionals, and a lean, with minimal overhead costs. The private equity firm then

concentrated incentives

high-powered efficient organization

managerial compensation, highly leveraged capital applied performance-based to the structures (often relying on junk bond financing), and active governance

isNeubauer Family Professor ofEntrepreneurship and Finance, Uni Steven N. Kaplan School ofBusiness, Chicago, Illinois. Per Str?mberg isProfessor Graduate versityof Chicago

ofFinance at theStockholm School ofEconomics and Director of theInstitutefor Financial Research (SIFR), both in Stockholm, Sweden. Both authors are also Research Associates, National

are

Bureau

of

Economic

([email protected])

Research,

Cambridge,

Massachusetts.

Their

e-mail

and ([email protected]).

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

addresses

122

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

in which

companies

invested.

and

leverage,

weak

to

According

to those of the typical public

superior low

it

A

governance.

corporate

with dispersed

corporation

few

shareholders, this

later,

years

were

structures

these

Jensen,

prediction

junk bond market crashed; a large number of high profile leveraged buyouts resulted in default and bankruptcy; and leveraged (so called public-to-private transactions) virtually buyouts of public companies by the early 1990s. disappeared seemed

The

premature.

But the leveraged buyout market had not died?it was only in hiding. While leveraged buyouts of public companies were relatively scarce during the 1990s to purchase private companies and early 2000s, private equity firms continued In

divisions.

and

the United buyout

the mid-2000s,

States

transactions

public-to-private

the rest of the world)

(and

when

reappeared

a second

experienced

leveraged

boom.

In 2006 and 2007, a record amount of capital was committed terms

in nominal

both

and

commitments

as

and

a fraction

of

rivaled,

if not

transactions

the overall

stock

overtook

the

to private equity,

market.

Private

equity

the first wave

of

activity

in the late 1980s that reached

its peak with the buyout of RJR Nabisco in 1988. in in with the turmoil the debt However, 2008, markets, private equity appears to have declined again. start the paper by describing

We describe the

equity

private

fundraising,

equity

typical

or SunGard

RJR Nabisco

leveraged

and

as

such

characteristics

and

KKR,

the

of

buyout

on how private

evidence

present

transaction

and

Carlyle,

transaction,

buyout

Systems. We

Data

activity,

as Blackstone,

such

organizations

of a

components

how the private equity industry works. We

have

over

varied

time.

The

article in

changes that

private

then considers structures,

capital

investors

equity

on

value

economic

and

This

then

evidence At

average.

equity. We and

incentives,

management introduce,

the effects of these changes. creates

the effects of private review

describe governance

corporate

the

the

evidence

empirical

on

suggests that private equity activity same

the

there

time,

is also

evidence

consistent with private equity investors taking advantage of market timing (and market mispricing) between debt and equity markets particularly in the public-to private

transactions also

We equity boom

at and

of

review

the

fund

bust

the

the

15 years.

that

on

evidence

empirical

level.

cycles

last

Private

equity

are

returns

past

returns

and to

appears

activity to

related

the economics

and

to

experience to

the

level

private

recurring of

interest

rates relative to earnings. Given that the unprecedented boom of 2005 to 2007 it seems likely that there will be a decline in private equity

has just ended, investment boom

may

and

in

fundraising

eventually

lead

to

the

some

next

several

defaults

and

years.

While

investor

the losses,

recent the

market

magnitude

is likely to be less severe than after the 1980s boom because capital structures are less fragile and private equity firms are more sophisticated. Accordingly, we expect that a significant part of the growth in private equity activity and institutions

is permanent.

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

StevenN. Kaplan

Private

Firms,

Equity

Blackstone,

and

Carlyle,

with

organizations

as a

are

KKR

equity firms. In the late 1980s, Jensen decentralized

123

and Transactions

Funds,

Private Equity Firms The typical private equity firm is organized corporation.

and Per Str?mberg

few

relatively

the most

prominent

private

these firms as

described

(1989)

or limited liability

partnership of

three

investment

lean, em

and

professionals

ployees. In his survey of seven large leveraged buyout partnerships, Jensen found an 13

of

average

investment

who

professionals,

tended

to come

an

from

investment

banking background. Today, the large private equity firms are substantially larger, are still small relative to the firms in which they invest. KKR's S-l (a although they in preparation for KKR's form filed with the Securities and Exchange Commission initial public offering) reported 139 investment professionals

other

large

firms

equity

private

to have

appear

more

sionals. In addition, private equity firms now appear wider

of

variety

and

skills

was

than

experience

true

than

in 2007. At least four

100

investment

profes

to employ professionals with a 20

years

ago.

Private Equity Funds A private equity firm raises equity capital through a private equity fund. Most private a

equity

are

funds

amount

certain

"closed-end"

of money

vehicles

to pay

for

in which

investors in

investments

to

commit as well

companies

provide as man

agement fees to the private equity firm.1 Legally, private equity funds are organized as limited partnerships in which the general partners manage the fund and the limited partners provide most of the capital. The limited partners typically include institutional and

insurance as

serves

such

investors,

the

companies, fund's

as

as

public

is customary

funds,

pension

individuals.

wealthy It

partner.

general

and

corporate

as well

The for

the

endowments,

private

firm

equity

to

partner

general

provide at least 1 percent of the total capital. The fund typicallyhas a fixed life,usually ten years, but can be extended forup to three additional years. The private equity firm normally has up to five years to invest the fund's capital committed into companies, and then has an additional five to eight years to return the capital to its investors.After committing their capital, the limited partners have little say in how the general partner deploys the investment funds, as long as the

basic

covenants

of

the

fund

agreement

are

followed.

Common

covenants

include

fund capital can be invested in one company, on types of securities a fund can invest in, and on debt at the fund level (as opposed to debt at the portfolio company level,which isunrestricted). Sahlman (1990), Gompers and Lerner restrictions on how much

(1996), and Axelson,

rationale

for

The the

1

equity

private

partner

general

In a "closed-end"

Str?mberg, and Weisbach

fund

these

fund,

(forthcoming) discuss the economic

structures. firm

earns

or an

is

general

partner

annual

management

investors cannot

withdraw

in three

compensated fee,

their funds until

usually

the fund

a

(2005)

of

is terminated.

funds, for example, where investors can withdraw their funds whenever for an economic funds. analysis of closed- vs. open-end

contrasts with mutual See Stein

First,

ways.

percentage

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

This

they like.

124

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

and

committed,

capital

the

Second,

employed.

to as

referred

"carried

as

then,

are

investments earns

partner

general

that

interest,"

almost

on

evidence

empirical

For

assume

example,

those a

that

share

always

general partners charge deal and monitoring invest. Metrick and Yasuda (2007) describe provide

a

a

realized, of

of

percentage

the

of

profits

20 percent.

equals

capital

the

fund, some

Finally,

fees to the companies inwhich the structure of fees in detail

they and

fees.

private

equity

firm, ABC

Partners,

a

raises

private

equity fund, ABC I, with $2 billion of capital commitments from limited partners. At a 2 percent management fee, ABC Partners would receive $40 million per year for the five-year investment period. This would decline over the following five years as ABC exited or sold its investments. The management fees typically end after ten years, although the fund can be extended thereafter. ABC would invest the differ ence between the $2 billion and the cumulative management fees into companies. IfABC's investments turned out to be successful and ABC was able to realize

would be entitled to a $6 billion from its investments?a profit of $4 billion?ABC carried interest or profit share of $800 million (or 20 percent of the $4 billion tomanagement fees of $300 to $400 million, ABC partners would profit). Added

have received a total of up to $1.2 billion over the fund's life. In addition,

sometimes

partners

general

are paid

deal

charge

and

fees

monitoring

that

to the general partner by the portfolio companies not by the limited partner. The extent to which these fees are shared with the limited partners is a issue

contentious

somewhat

in

fundraising

These

negotiations.

fees

are

commonly

split 50-50 between general and limited partners. The Private Equity Analyst (2008) lists 33 global private equity firms (22 U.S. at the end of 2007. based) with more than $10 billion of assets under management The same publication lists the top 25 investors in private equity. Those investors are (California Public Employees' by public pension funds, with CalPERS CalSTERS State Teachers' Retirement System), (California System), Public School Retirement System), and theWash (Pennsylvania Employees'

dominated

Retirement PSERS

ington State Investment Board

the top four slots.

occupying

Private Equity Transactions In a typical private equity transaction, the private equity firm agrees to buy a company. If the company is public, the private equity firm typically pays a premium

of 15 to 50 percent over the current stock price (Kaplan, 1989b; Bargeron, Schlingemann, Stulz, and Zutter, 2007). The buyout is typically financed with 60 to the term, leveraged buyout. The debt almost always 90 percent debt?hence includes

a

loan

portion

that

is senior

and

secured,

and

is

arranged

by

a bank

or

an

investment bank. In the 1980s and 1990s, banks were also the primary investors in these

loans.

More

recently,

fraction of the senior and investors

and

"collateralized

however,

institutional

secured

loans. Those

loan

obligation"

managers,

investors

a

purchased

investors include hedge who

combine

a number

large

fund of

term loans into a pool and then carve the pool into different pieces (with different seniority) to sell to institutional investors. The debt in leveraged buyouts also often includes a junior, unsecured portion that is financed by either high-yield

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity

Figure 1 U.S. Private Equity Fundraising and Transaction U.S. Stock Market Value from 1985 to 2007

Values

as a Percentage

125

of Total

,_,

3.50%n

Sources: Private Equity Analyst, CapitallQ,

bonds or "mezzanine

Str?mberg

(2008),

authors'

calculations.

(that is, debt that is subordinated to the senior debt). (2007) and Standard and Poor's (2008) provide more

debt"

and James Demiroglu detailed descriptions.

The private equity firm invests funds from its investors as equity to cover the team of remaining 10 to 40 percent of the purchase price. The new management the purchased

(which may or may not be identical to the pre-buyout typically also contributes to the new equity, although the

company

team) management amount is usually a small fraction of the equity dollars contributed. 2005 buyout of Sun (2005) describes a large leveraged buyout?the Kaplan Gard Data Systems?in detail. Axelson, Jenkinson, Str?mberg, and Weisbach (2008) provide a detailed

description

of capital structures in these kinds of lever

aged buyouts. to Private Equity Funds Private equity funds first emerged in the early 1980s. Nominal dollars committed each year to U.S. private equity funds have increased exponentially since then, from

Commitments

$0.2 billion in 1980 to over $200 billion in 2007. Given the large increase in firmmarket values over this period, it ismore appropriate to measure committed capital as a

percentage of the total value of theU.S. stockmarket. The deflated series, presented in Figure 1, suggests thatprivate equity commitments are cyclical. They increased in the 1980s, peaked in 1988, declined in the early 1990s, increased through the late 1990s,

peaked in 1998, declined again in the early 2000s, and then began climbing in 2003. By 2006 and 2007, private equity commitments appeared extremely high by historical standards, exceeding 1 percent of the U.S. stock market's value One caveat to this observation

is that many of the large U.S. private equity firms have only recently global in scope. Foreign investments by U.S. private equity firms were much smaller 20 years ago, so the comparisons are not exacdy apples to apples.

become

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

126

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

Figure 2 Global Private Equity Transaction

Volume,

1985-2006

information on capital commitments to Although we do not have comparable non-U.S. funds, it is clear that they also have grown substantially. In 2007, the Private Equity Analyst lists three non-U.S. private equity firms among the twelve largest in the world

in assets

under

management.

Private Equity Transactions Figure 2 shows the number

and

combined

transaction value

of worldwide

leveraged buyout transactions backed by a private equity fund sponsor based on In total, 17,171 private equity-sponsored buyout transactions data from CapitallQ. occurred from January 1, 1970, to June 30, 2007. (This excludes transactions

but not completed by November 1, 2007.) Transaction values equal the enterprise value (market value of equity plus book value of debt minus cash) of the transaction values are not acquired firms, converted into 2007 U.S. dollars. When announced

(generally smaller, private-to-private deals), we impute values as a func tion of various deal and sponsor characteristics. Figure 1 also uses the CapitallQ data to report the combined transaction value of U.S. leveraged buyouts backed by a private equity fund sponsor as a fraction of total U.S. stock market value. recorded

and discusses potential Str?mberg (2008) describes the sampling methodology biases. The most important qualification is that CapitallQ may underreport private equity transactions before the mid-1990s, particularly smaller transactions. Overall

buyout transaction activitymirrors the patterns in private equity fund Transaction and fundraising volumes exhibit a similar cyclicality. Transac raising. tion values peaked in 1988; dropped during the early 1990s, rose and peaked in the later 1990s, dropped in the early 2000s; and increased dramatically from 2004 to

2006. A huge fraction of historic buyout activity has taken place within the last few recorded 5,188 buyout transactions years. From 2005 through June 2007, CapitallQ

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

StevenN. Kaplan

and Per Str?mberg

127

Table 1 Global

1985-1989

LBOs

1990-1994

$257,214 642

enterprise value of transactions

Combined Number

across Time

Characteristics

Buyout Transaction

Leveraged

2000-2004

1995-1999

,614

$553,852

1,123

L,055,070

4,348

2005-6/

1970-6/

30/2007

30/2007

1,563,250

$3,616,787

5,188

5,673

17,171

by type: (% of combined

enterprise value) Public to private

49% 31% 17% 2% 0%

private

Independent Divisional Secondary Distressed

54% 31% 6% 1%

15% 44% 27% 13% 1%

18% 19% 41% 20%

34% 14% 25% 26% 1%

27% 23% 30% 20%

72% 13% 13%

60% 16% 20%

44% 17% 32%

47% 15% 30%

52% 15% 26%

4%

6%

4% 3%

by target location: (% of combined

LBOs

enterprise value) United States and Canada United Western

7%

Kingdom

UK)

Europe

(except

1% 2%

3%

Asia and Australia Rest ofWorld

3%

for 17,171 worldwide table reports transaction characteristics leveraged buyout transactions database announced between every transaction with a financial sponsor in the CapitallQ sum is net the of to pay for the value and and 6/30/2007. debt used 1/1/1970 Enterprise equity of 2007 U.S. dollars. For the transactions where in millions transaction value was not enterprise

Note: The

that include

recorded,

these have been

imputed using

in Str?mberg

the methodology

(2008).

estimated enterprise value of over $1.6 trillion (in 2007 dollars), with those 2*/2years accounting for 30 percent of the transactions from 1984 to 2007 and

at a combined 43

of

percent

total

the

real

transaction

value,

respectively.

2006 Although Figure 2 only includes deals announced through December 2007), the number of announced (and closed by November leveraged buyouts continued to increase until June 2007 when a record number of 322 deals were

After that, deal activity decreased substantially in the wake of the new buyouts were announced. In in markets. 133 turmoil credit January 2008, only

announced. As

the

private

market

equity

evolved, as summarized The

analysis. some

extent

first, a U.K.,

late

has

in Table 1980s

buyout

grown,

wave From

phenomenon.

transaction

1; Str?mberg was

(2008)

presents a U.S.,

primarily

1985-89,

these

also

characteristics

three

a more

and

Canadian, countries

have

detailed to

accounted

for 89 percent of worldwide leveraged buyout transactions and 93 percent of transaction value. The leveraged buyout business was dominated by worldwide relatively

large

transactions,

in mature

industries

(such

as

manufacturing

and

retail); public-to-private deals accounted for almost half of the value of the trans actions. These transactions in the first buyout wave helped form the perception of private equity that persisted formany years: leveraged buyouts equal going-private transactions

of

large

firms

in mature

industries.

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

128

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

Following the fall of the junk bond market in the late 1980s, public-to-private activity declined significantly, dropping to less than 10 percent of transaction value, while the average enterprise value of companies acquired dropped from $401 million to $132 million (both in 2007 dollars). Instead, "middle-market" buyouts of traded firms?either independent companies or divisions of larger non-publicly for the bulk of private equity significantly and accounted new as information to industries such activity. Buyout activity spread technology/ corporations?grew

financial

media/telecommunications,

ing and retail firms became value

transaction

as

twice

fell,

and

services,

were

deals

many

care

health

as buyout

less dominant

while

manufactur

targets. Although in

undertaken

aggregate versus

1990-94

1985-89. As private equity activity experienced steady growth over the following period a in for the market continued to evolve. from 1995-2004 2000-2001), dip (except

Public

company

accounted

An

transactions.

increased,

buyouts

for over

80

of

percent

transaction

fraction

increasing

buyouts of private companies

although of

buyouts

more

value

and

were

so-called

than

90

still of

percent

secondary

buyouts?

private equity funds exiting their old investments and selling portfolio companies to other private equity firms. By the early 2000-2004 period, secondary buyouts comprised over 20 percent of total transaction value. The largest sources of deals in this

were

however,

period,

large

corporations

off divisions.

selling

theWestern Euro Buyouts also spread rapidly to Europe. From 2000-2004, market the United had 48.9 percent of pean private equity (including Kingdom) worldwide leveraged buyout transaction value, compared with 43.7 percent in the States. The scope of the industry also continued to broaden, with compa nies in services and infrastructure becoming increasingly popular buyout targets. The private equity boom from 2005 to mid-2007 magnified many of these

United

trends.

Public-to-private

together accounting

over

value

transaction

and

formore this

secondary

grew

buyouts

in numbers

rapidly

and

size,

than 60 percent of the $1.6 trillion leveraged buyout

time.

in

Buyouts

industries

nonmanufacturing

contin

to grow in relative importance, and private equity activity spread to new parts of the world, particularly Asia (although levels were modest compared toWestern

ued

and

Europe

As

America).

(deflated) deal

average

large

transactions

public-to-private

sizes almost tripled between

returned,

2001 and 2006.

and Timing of Exit

Manner

Because ment

North

exits

most are

an

private important

equity aspect

funds of

have the

a

private

limited

contractual

equity

process.

lifetime, Table

invest

2 presents

statistics on private equity investment exits using the CapitallQ buyout sample. The top panel shows the frequency of various exits. Given that so many leveraged

buyouts occurred recently, it is not surprising that 54 percent of the 17,171 sample transactions (going back to 1970) had not yet been exited by November 2007. This raises

two

important

issues.

First,

any

conclusions

about

the

long-run

economic

impact of leveraged buyouts may be premature. Second, empirical analyses of the performance of leveraged buyouts will likely suffer from selection bias to the extent they

only

consider

realized

investments.

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

129

Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity

Table 2 of Leveraged

Exit Characteristics

1970-

across Time

1990-

1985-

1984

Year oforiginal LBO Type

Buyouts

1995-

2000-

2003-

2006-

Whole

1989

1994

1999

2002

2005

2007

period

6% 25%

5% 23%

8% 11%

6% 9%

3% 6% 11%

3% 1%

14%

35%

38%

40%

37%

13% 3%

17% 3%

23% 5%

31% 6%

of exit:

7% IPO 28%

Bankruptcy to strategic buyer

Sold

31%

5% 2%

Secondarybuyout Sold toLBO-backed firm to management

Sold

40%

38% 35%

24% 31% 7% 5%

17% 19%

1%

1%

1%

2%

2% 1% 1%

1%

Other/unknown

26%

18%

12%

11%

10%

7%

No exit byNov. 2007

3%

5%

9%

27%

43%

98% 74%

54%

14% 47% 53% 61% 70%

12% 40% 48% 58% 75%

14% 53% 63% 70% 82%

13% 41% 49% 56% 76% 73%

9% 42% 40% 49% 51% 55% 58%

13%

12%

% of deals

11% 24%

exited within

24months (2 years) 60 months (5 years) 72months (6 years) 84 months (7 years) 120months (10 years)

table reports exit information for 17,171 worldwide leveraged buyout transactions that include database announced between 1/1/1970 and every transaction with a financial sponsor in the CapitallQ of transactions, on an equally-weighted basis. The numbers are expressed as a percentage 6/30/2007.

Note: The

Exit status is determined and Lerner detailed

(2007),

description

SDC, Worldscope, Amadeus, Cao, using various databases, including CapitallQ, as well as company and LBO firm web sites. See (2008) for a more Str?mberg

of the methodology.

on

Conditional

company second

common

most

exit

is a

sale

common

the most

exited,

having

buyer; this occurs

to a strategic (nonfinancial)

to another

private

route

is

the

sale

of

the

in 38 percent of exits. The equity

fund

in a

secondary

considerably over time. leveraged buyout (24 percent); Initial public offerings, where the company is listed on a public stock exchange (and the private equity firm can subsequently sell its shares in the public market), account for 14 percent of exits; this route has decreased significantly in relative this route has

over

importance

increased

time.

the high debt levels in these transactions, one might expect a nontrivial fraction of leveraged buyouts to end in bankruptcy. For the total sample, 6 percent of deals have ended in bankruptcy or reorganization. Excluding post-2002 lever Given

aged buyouts, which may not have had enough time to enter financial distress, the incidence increases to 7 percent. Assuming an average holding period of six years, out

this works

to an

annual

rate

default

of

1.2

percent

per

year.

Perhaps

surpris

ingly, this is lower than the average default rate of 1.6 percent thatMoody's reports for all U.S. corporate bond issuers from 1980-2002 (Hamilton et al., 2006). One caveat is that not all cases of distress may be recorded in publicly available data sources;

some

of

these

cases

may

be

"hidden"

in

the

relatively

large

fraction

of

exits (11 percent). Perhaps consistent with this,Andrade and Kaplan find that 23 percent of the larger public-to-private transactions of the 1980s (1998)

"unknown" defaulted

at

some

point.

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

130

The

bottom panel

2 shows average holding

The

transactions.

buyout

leveraged

of Table

on

is done

analysis

for individual

periods

a cohort

to avoid

basis,

the

bias resulting from older deals being more likely to have been exited. Over the whole sample, the median holding period is roughly six years, but this has varied over time. Median holding periods were less than five years for deals from the early affected by the "hot" initial public offering markets

1990s, presumably 1990s. oriented, ownership

companies

investment,

funds have

increased

been

accused

of

sustained

In our

time.

more

becoming

common.

Instead,

we

analysis,

as exits within 24 months

more

become

within 24 months

a

for

that "quick flips," defined have

have

short-term

to "flip" their investments rather than to maintain

preferring of

funds

equity

private

Recently,

of the late

see

no

their

evidence

of the private equity fund's

holding

of

periods

private

equity

since the 1990s. Overall, only 12 percent of deals are exited of the leveraged buyout acquisition date.

Finally, because of the high fraction of secondary buyouts in recent years, the individual holding periods understate the total time in which leveraged buyout firms are held by private equity funds. Accounting for secondary buyouts, Str?m leveraged buyout is still in private equity berg (2008) shows that the median nine

ownership

after

years

the original

buyout

transaction.

In

comparison,

Kaplan

lever (1991), who also takes secondary buyouts into account, found the median aged-buyout target remained in private ownership for 6.82 years, which is consistent with privately owned holding periods having increased since the 1980s.

Is Private Equity a Superior Organizational

Form?

Proponents of leveraged buyouts, like Jensen (1989), argue that private equity firms apply financial, governance, and operational engineering to their portfolio and,

companies, In

superior

in so

some

contrast,

doing,

argue

information,

improve

that but

private

do

not

firm equity

create

and

operations firms any

take

create

advantage value.

operational

economic of

value.

tax breaks

and critics

Moreover,

sometimes argue that private equity activity is influenced by market timing (and market mispricing) between debt and equity markets. In this section, we consider the proponents' views and the first set of criticisms about whether private equity creates more

value.

operational

In

the next

section,

we

consider

market

timing

issues

in

detail.

and Operational Financial, Governance, Engineering firms Private equity apply three sets of changes invest,

which

we

categorize

as financial,

governance,

to the firms in which and

operational

they

engineering.

and Kaplan (1989a, b) describe the financial and governance with associated private equity. First, private equity firms pay engineering changes to incentives in their portfolio companies. They careful attention management Jensen

(1989)

team a large equity upside through stock and typically give the management was unusual among public firms in the early 1980s (Jensen that options?a practice

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

StevenN. Kaplan

and Per Str?mberg

131

and Murphy, 1990). Kaplan (1989b) finds that management ownership percent a to four in from factor of increase ages going private ownership. Private by public firms

equity

also

require

company, downside

as well.

a

to make

management

so thatmanagement

investment

meaningful

in

the

not only has a significant upside, but a significant because

Moreover,

the

are

companies

private,

management's

cannot sell its equity or exercise its is,management equity is illiquid?that options until the value is proved by an exit transaction. This illiquidity reduces manage ment's

to

incentive It remains

the

manipulate case that

short-term

performance. teams

management

obtain

significant

in

stakes

equity

portfolio companies. We collected information on 43 leveraged buyouts in the United States from 1996 to 2004 with a median transaction value of over $300 Of

million.

these,

23 were

The

transactions.

public-to-private

median

execu

chief

tive officer receives 5.4 percent of the equity upside (stock and options) while the team as a whole gets 16 percent. Acharya and Kehoe (2008) find management trans similar results in the United Kingdom for 59 large buyouts (with a median action value of over $500 million) officer

executive

gets

3 percent

from 1997 to 2004. They report themedian

of

the

the median

equity;

chief

team

management

as

a

gets 15 percent. These magnitudes are similar to those in the 1980s public (1989b). Even though stock- and option to-private transactions studied by Kaplan more have become based compensation widely used in public firms since the 1980s,

whole

(and upside) remain greater in leveraged ownership percentages management's in than buyouts public companies. The second key ingredient is leverage?the borrowing that is done in connec tion

with

the

transaction.

Leverage

creates

pressure

on

not

managers

to waste

money, because they must make interest and principal payments. This pressure in Jensen reduces the "free cash flow" problems described (1986), in which management

dissipate and

many

teams

in mature

industries

with

weak

corporate

governance

cash flows rather than returning them to investors.2 In the United other

countries,

leverage

also

potentially

increases

firm

value

could

States through

the tax deductibility of interest. On the flip side, if leverage is too high, the inflexibility of the required payments (as contrasted with the flexibility of payments to equity) increases the chance of costly financial distress.

Third, governance engineering refers to the way that private equity investors control the boards of their portfolio companies and are more actively involved in governance than public company boards. Private equity portfolio company boards are smaller than comparable public company boards and meet more frequently 1996; Acharya and Kehoe, 2008; Cornelli and Karakas, (Gertner and Kaplan, (2008) report that portfolio companies have twelve 2008).3 Acharya and Kehoe formal

meetings

per

year

and

many

more

informal

contacts.

In

addition,

2 Axelson,

private

also argue that leverage provides discipline to the (forthcoming) Str?mberg, and Weisbach debt providers?to acquiring leveraged buyout fund, which must persuade third-party investors?the co-invest in each deal. 3 evidence on public firm boards (Yermack, 1996) suggests that smaller boards are more Empirical efficient.

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

132

Acharya firms are replaced a

four-year

to

hesitate

poorly

replace

management.

performing

(2008) report that one-third of chief executive officers of these in the first 100 days while two-thirds are replaced at some point

and Kehoe

over

not

do

investors

equity

period.

and governance engineering were common by the late 1980s. Today, most large private equity firms have added another type that we call "operational engineering," which refers to industry and operating expertise that they apply to Financial

add

to

value

investments.

their

most

Indeed,

top

private

are

firms

equity

now

to hiring dealmakers with financial engi organized now firms often hire professionals with operating neering skills, private equity industries. In addition

around

an

and

backgrounds

For

focus.

industry

Lou

example,

the

Gerstner,

former

chief

executive officer of RJR and IBM is affiliated with Carlyle, while Jack Welch, former chief executive officer of GE, is affiliated with Clayton Dubilier. Most firms

equity

private

also

use

make

Private equity firms use

attractive

to

investments, the value

implement

or

internal

value plans.

A

creation plan

might

improvements, productivity as well as management opportunities,

acquisition

and MacArthur,

2008; Gadiesh

and Kehoe,

strategic

and

investments,

elements changes

changes

to identify

knowledge

those

include

and

top

groups.

consulting

for

plans

and

opportunities

external

their industry and operating

develop

creation

of

the

of or

to

cost-cutting

repositioning, (Acharya

upgrades

2008).

Operating Performance The empirical evidence on the operating performance of companies after they have been purchased through a leveraged buyout is largely positive. For U.S. in deals the 1980s, Kaplan (1989b) finds that the ratio of operating public-to-private to to 10 sales increased by income 20 percent (absolutely and relative to industry). to sales in ratio of cash flow (operating income less capital expenditures) creased by roughly 40 percent. The ratio of capital expenditures to sales declined. These changes are coincident with large increases in firm value (again, absolutely and relative to industry). Smith (1990) finds similar results. Lichtenberg and Siegel

The

(1990) find that leveraged buyouts experience productivity after the buyout.

significant increases

in total factor

on private equity and leverage buyouts has post-1980s empirical work on focused buyouts in Europe, largely because of data availability. Consistent with the U.S. results from the 1980s, most of this work finds that leveraged buyouts are Most

with significant operating and productivity improvements. This work includes Harris, Siegel, and Wright (2005) for the United Kingdom; Boucly, Sraer, and Thesmar (2008) for France; and Bergstr?m, Grubb, and Jonsson (2007) for Sweden. Cumming, Siegel, and Wright (2007) summarize much of this literature

associated

and

there

conclude

"is a

general

consensus

across

different

mea

methodologies,

sures, and time periods regarding a key stylized fact: LBOs [leveraged buyouts] and [management buyouts] enhance performance and have a salient especially MBOs effect

on

work

There results?more

practices."

has been recent

one

exception

public-to-private

to the largely uniform positive buyouts.

Guo

et al.

(2007)

operating

study U.S.

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

public

Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity

133

to 2006. The 94 leveraged buyouts to-private transactions completed from 1990 are concentrated in deals completed by 2000. The with available post-buyout data

in operating and cash flow margins that are much in the 1980s data for the United States and in the

increases

authors find modest

than those found

smaller

data. At the same

time, they find high investor returns (adjusted for industry or the overall stock market) at the portfolio company level. Acharya and Kehoe (2008) and Weir, Jones, and Wright (2007) find similarlymodest operating European

over roughly the improvements for public-to-private deals in the United Kingdom same period. Nevertheless, Acharya and Kehoe also find (2008) high investor

returns.

These

results

that

suggest

post-1980s

transactions

public-to-private

may

differ from those of the 1980s and from leveraged buyouts overall. the empirical evidence is consistent overall with significant operating While some caution. improvements for leverage buyouts, it should be interpreted with First, some

studies, particularly

those in the United

because

data

to selection

subject

For

available.

bias

most

example,

U.S.

performance

for

of financial

studies

States, are potentially

private

are

firms

performance

not

study

always

leveraged

buyouts that use public debt or subsequently go public, and leveraged buyouts of public companies. These may not be representative of the population. Still, studies in countries

undertaken

not

do

therefore

where

suffer

reporting

data

accounting biases?for

on

is available

example,

Boucly,

private Sraer,

firms, which and

Thesmar

and Bergstr?m, Grubb, and Jonsson (2007) for Sweden?find (2008) significant operating improvements after leveraged buyouts. Second, the decline in capital expenditures found in some studies raises the for France

current cash flows, but hurt future possibility that leveraged buyouts may increase to concern at the performance of leveraged test is look this of cash flows. One an initial public offering. In a buyout companies after they have gone through recent paper, Cao and Lerner (2007) find positive industry-adjusted stock perfor mance

such

after

initial

public

In

offerings.

another

test

of whether

future

pros

pects are sacrificed to current cash flow, Lerner, Sorensen, and Str?mberg (2008) as measured by patenting. Although study post-buyout changes in innovation relatively few private equity portfolio companies do

patent

focus

experience

Furthermore,

patenting.

portant

not

(as measured

their

innovation

any patents

meaningful filed

by subsequent activities

decline

post-buyout

citations)

in a few

core

engage in

in patenting,

post-buyout

appear

more

those that

innovation economically

or im

than those filed pre-buyout, as firms

areas.

Overall, interpret the empirical evidence as largely consistent with the existence of operating and productivity improvements after leveraged buyouts. Most of these results are based on leveraged buyouts completed before the latest we

private

pleted

equity

wave.

Accordingly,

the

performance

in the latest private equity wave

of

leveraged

is clearly a desirable

buyouts

com

topic for future

research.

Employment Critics of leveraged buyouts often argue that these transactions benefit private equity investors at the expense of employees who suffer job and wage cuts.While

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

134

such reductions would be consistent the political

improvements,

operating this manner

be more

would

(and arguably expected) with productivity and implications of economic gains achieved in see

(for example,

negative

comments

from

the

Service

Employees International Union, 2007). (1989b) studies U.S. public-to-private buyouts in the 1980s and finds Kaplan that employment increases post-buyout, but by less than other firms in the industry.

a similar result. Davis, Haltiwanger, Jarmin, Lichtenberg and Siegel (1990) obtain a Miranda and Lerner, (2008) study large sample of U.S. leveraged buyouts from at the establishment level. They find that employment at leveraged 1980 to 2005 firms increases by less than at other firms in the same industry after the buyout buyout, but also find that leveraged buyout firms had smaller employment before

the

The

transaction.

buyout

relative

in retail businesses. They find no difference sector.

For

a

subset

of

at new

employment

their

sample,

as well

establishments

similar

as

at

al.

ones.

existing

in the manufacturing are

(2008)

to measure

able

For

this

subsample,

firms.

non-buyout

the United

Outside

States, Amess, and Wright (2007a) study buyouts in the from 1999 to 2004 and find that firms that experience leveraged

United Kingdom have

buyouts

et

growth

concentrated

have higher job growth in new establishments

the leveraged buyout companies than

in employment

Davis

are

declines

employment

employment

to other

similar

growth

but

firms,

increase

more

wages

slowly.The one exception to the findings in the United States and United Kingdom are those for France by Boucly, Sraer, and Thesmar (2008), who find that leveraged companies

buyout

experience

and wage

greater job

growth than other

similar

companies. then,

Overall,

leveraged

experience are

findings

not

the

evidence

buyouts,

consistent

with

that

suggests but

at a slower

concerns

employment

rate

over

than

at other

destruction,

job

at

grows similar but

firms

firms.

neither

that These

are

they

consistent with the opposite position that firms owned by private industry experi ence especially strong employment growth (except, perhaps, in France). We view the empirical evidence on employment

equity

portfolio

companies

create

as largely consistent with a view that private

economic

value

by operating

more

efficiently.

Taxes

debt in leveraged buyout transactions gives rise to interest tax are deductions that valuable, but difficult to value accurately. Kaplan (1989a) finds that, depending on the assumption, the reduced taxes from higher interest deduc The

additional

tions can explain from 4 percent to 40 percent of a firm's value. The lower estimates assume that leveraged buyout debt is repaid in eight years and that personal taxes offset the benefit of corporate tax deductions. The higher estimates assume that leveraged buyout debt ispermanent offset.

Assuming

that

the

truth

lies between

estimate of the value of lower taxes due

these

and that personal various

to increased

assumptions,

taxes provide no a reasonable

leverage for the 1980s might estimates would be lower for leveraged

be 10 to 20 percent of firm value. These buyouts in the 1990s and 2000s, because both the corporate tax rate and the extent of leverage used in these deals have declined. Thus, while greater leverage creates

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

StevenN. Kaplan

and Per Str?mberg

135

some value for private equity investors by reducing taxes, it is difficult to say exactly how

much.

Asymmetric Information The

favorable

generally

are also potentially mation

on

claim

that

future

results

on

operating

company

portfolio

incumbent

Critics

performance. is a

management

on

information

value

creation

consistent with private equity investors having superior source

of

this

extent, supporters of private equity implicitly agree has

and

improvements

a

to make

how

firm

of

inside

private

infor often

equity

information.

some

To

that incumbent management better.

perform

After

all,

one

of

the

justifications for private equity deals is that with better incentives and closer to deliver better results. A less monitoring, managers will use their knowledge attractive

claim,

is that

however,

they intend to keep

because the new

owners.

a result,

As

incumbent

favor

managers

a

private

equity

their jobs and receive lucrative compensation incumbent

managers

highest price for existing shareholders?thus

may

be

to

unwilling

fight

buyout

under for

the

giving private equity investors a better

deal.

Several observations

suggest that it is unlikely that operating improvements are a result of simply private equity firms taking advantage of private information. First, studies the forecasts the private equity firms released Kaplan (1989b) publicly at the time of the leveraged buyout. The asymmetric information story suggests that actual should

performance

exceed

the

forecasts.

In

fact,

actual

after

performance

the

buyout lags the forecasts. Moreover, Ofek (1994) studies leveraged buyout attempts that failed because the offer was rejected by the board or by stockholders (even though management supported it) and finds no excess stock returns or operating improvements for these firms. It would be useful to replicate these studies with more

recent

transactions.

Second,

firms

equity

private

tioned

frequently

bring

and Kehoe

in new

men

As

management.

earlier, Acharya (2008) report that one-third of the chief executive officers in their sample are replaced in the first 100 days and two-thirds are

over

replaced

a

four-year

that itwill be in a position

Thus,

incumbent

owners.

equity

Third, firms

period.

to receive high-powered

have

it seems likely that at times in the boom-and-bust in their

overpaid

leveraged

buyouts

and

cannot

management

be

sure

incentives from the new private

experienced

cycle, private equity losses.

For

exam

ple, the late 1980s was one such time, and it seems likely that the tail end of the private equity boom in 2006 and into early 2007 will generate lower returns than investors

as well.

expected

If incumbent

management

provided

inside

information,

it clearly wasn't enough to avoid periods of poor returns for private equity funds. While these findings are inconsistent with operating improvements being the result of asymmetric information, there is some evidence that private equity funds are able to acquire firms more than other et bidders. Guo al. cheaply (2007) and Acharya

and Kehoe

only modest

perience large financial

(2008) find that post-1980s public-to-private transactions ex increases in firm operating performance, but still generate

returns to private equity funds. This finding suggests that private

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

136

equity firms are able to buy low and sell high. Similarly, Bargeron, Schlingemann, Stulz, and Zutter (2007) find that private equity firms pay lower premiums than are consistent with public company buyers in cash acquisitions. These findings or industries that turn out to be under private equity firms identifying companies valued. Alternatively, this could indicate that private equity firms are particularly boards

target

and

not

do

management

the best

get

in these acquisitions.

possible price Overall,

that

and/or

negotiators,

good

then,

the

not

does

evidence

an

support

The

management.

are

results

consistent

potentially

for

role

important

on the part of private equity firm-specific information

investors and

with

private

superior

incumbent investors

equity

bargaining well, target boards bargaining badly, or private equity investors taking advantage of market timing (and market mispricing), which we discuss below.

Private Equity Fund Returns company-level empirical evidence suggests that leveraged buyouts by private equity firms create value (adjusted for industry and market). This evidence The not

does

necessarily

that

however,

imply,

private

equity

funds

earn

returns

superior

for their limited partner investors. First, because private equity firms often purchase firms in competitive auctions or by paying a premium to public shareholders, sellers likely

a

capture

amount

meaningful

of value.

For

in KKR's

example,

of

purchase

RJR Nabisco, KKR paid a premium to public shareholders of roughly $10 billion. After the buyout, KKR's investors earned a low return, suggesting thatKKR paid out

most, ifnot all of the value-added toRJR's public shareholders. Second, the limited partner investors in private equity funds pay meaningful fees. Metrick and Yasuda (2007) estimate that fees equal $19 in present value per $100 of capital under for

management net

investors

the median

of

fees

will

private be

lower

fund.

equity than

As

return

the

a result, on

the

the

return

private

to outside fund's

equity

investments.

underlying

Kaplan and Schoar (2005) study the returns to private equity and venture an investor (or limited capital funds. They compare how much partner) in a private net to fees what the of investor would have earned in an fund earned equity equivalent investment in the Standard and Poor's 500 index. They find that private equity fund investors earn slightly less than the Standard and Poor's 500 index net of

fees,

ending

with

an

average

ratio

of

93

percent

to 97

percent.

On

average,

therefore, they do not find the outperformance often given as a justification for investing in private equity funds. At the same time, however, these results imply that the private equity investors outperform the Standard and Poor's 500 index gross of fees

(that

is, when

fees

are

added

back).

Those

returns,

therefore,

are

consistent

with private equity investors adding value (over and above the premium paid to selling shareholders). At least two caveats are in order. First, Kaplan and Schoar (2005) use data from VentureEconomics which samples only roughly half of private equity funds, leaving an unknown

and

potentially

important

selection

bias.

Second,

because

of data

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

avail

Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity

issues,

ability

and

Kaplan

Schoar

compare

to the Standard

performance

500 index without making any adjustments for risk. Kaplan and Schoar (2005) also find strong evidence mance?that

mance

is, performance

private

because

In contrast,

funds

persistence

little

show

result

are

funds

worst-performing

mutual

This

persistence.

the

equity

of persistence

in one

firm

fund

Poor's

in perfor

predicts

perfor

funds. In fact, their results likely understate

by the firm in subsequent

persistence fund.

by

a

and

137

persistence

explains

less and

limited

why

likely hedge

a

to raise funds often

partners

subsequent

show

uncertain

strive

to invest

in private equity funds thathave been among the top performers in the past (Swensen, Of

2000).

course,

only

some

limited

partners

can

succeed

in such

a

strategy.

Phalippou and Gottschalg (forthcoming) use a slightly updated version of the Kaplan and Schoar (2005) data set. They obtain qualitatively identical results to (2005) for the average returns and persistence of private Kaplan and Schoar funds relevant here.

equity/buyout

Boom

and Bust Cycles in Private Equity

Portfolio Company The

of

pattern

decades

suggests

Level

that

equity

private credit

market

commitments conditions

and

may

transactions

affect

this

activity.

over One

recent hypoth

esis is that private equity investors take advantage of systematic mispricings in the debt and equity markets. That is,when the cost of debt is relatively low compared to the cost of equity, private equity can arbitrage or benefit from the difference. This argument relies on the existence of market frictions that enable debt and equity markets to become and Wurgler Greenwood, of market

advantage

(2000) and Baker, segmented. Baker and Wurgler take (2003) offer arguments that public companies

mispricing.

see how debt mispricing might matter, assume that a public company is run a can and If firm borrow at a rate unleveraged private equity being optimally. too low given the risk, the private equity firm will create value by borrowing. that is To

In

the

recent

wave,

interest

rate

spreads

for

private

equity

borrowing

increased

from roughly 250 basis points over the benchmark LIBOR (London Interbank in 2006 to 500 basis points over LIBOR Offered Rate) in 2008 (Standard and Poor's, 2008). Under the assumptions that debt funds 70 percent of the purchase

price and has a maturity of eight years, debt mispricing of 250 basis points would justify roughly 10 percent of the purchase price or, equivalently, would allow a

private equity fund investor to pay an additional 10 percent (that is, the present value of an eight-year loan for 70 discounted at the higher interest rate is 60, not 70). The mispricing theory implies that relatively more deals will be undertaken when debt markets are unusually favorable. Kaplan and Stein (1993) present

consistent with a role for overly favorable terms from high-yield bond investors in the 1980s buyout wave. The credit market turmoil in late 2007 and early

evidence

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

138

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

Figure 3

in Large U.S. Public-to-Private Buyouts, 1982 to 2006 Enterprise Value to EBITDA " a measure cash (UEBITDA, of flow, standsfor earnings before interest,taxes, depreciation, and amortization) 12.00 10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00

\\\\\\\\

\\\\\%\\\\

Source: Kaplan and Sein (1993) and Guo, Note: The first private equity wave began in 2007. 2003 or 2004 and ended

and Song (2007). Hotchkiss, in 1982 or 1983 and ended in 1989;

the second

began

in

2008 suggests that overly favorable terms from debt investors may have helped fuel the buyout wave from 2005 through mid-2007. To study buyout market cyclicality, we make more detailed "apples-to-apples" comparisons of buyout characteristics over time by combining the results in Kaplan

(1993) for the 1980s buyout wave with those in Guo et al. (2007) for the last ten years. Both papers study public-to-private transactions in the United States. First, we look at valuations or prices relative to cash flow. To measure the price

and Stein

paid for these deals, we calculate enterprise value as the sum of the value of equity and net debt at the time of the buyout. Firm cash flow is calculated using the standard measure

of firm-level performance, EBITDA, which stands for earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization. Figure 3 reports themedian ratio of enterprise value to cash flow for leveraged buyouts by year. The figure shows that prices paid for cash flow were generally higher at the end of the buyout

waves

than at the beginning. (The firstprivate equity wave began in 1982 or 1983 and ended in 1989; the second began in 2003 or 2004 and ended in 2007.) The more recent period, in particular, exhibits a great deal of cyclicality, first dipping substantially from 2000 through 2002, and then rising afterwards. Figure 3 also shows that valuation multiples in the recent wave exceeded those

in the 1980s wave, although this conclusion is open to some interpretation. In to were higher in the last decade ratios all of values cash flow corporate general,

the ratios in Figure 3 are deflated by the median ratio for nonfinancial companies in the Standard and Poor's 500 index, the valuations of to the Standard and Poor's 500 are slightly lower in deals relative leveraged buyout than in the 1980s. When

the

recent

wave

relative

to

the

previous

wave.

Even

after

such

a

calculation,

cyclicality of the recent wave remains.

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

the

StevenN. Kaplan

and Per Str?mberg

139

Figure 4 EBITDA

to Interest in Large U.S. Public to Private Buyouts, 1982 to 2006 " a measure of cashflow, standsfor earnings before interest,taxes, ("EBITDA, depreciation, and amortization)

\\\\\W\

'%W\\W\X'

Source: Kaplan and Stein (1993) and Guo, Hotchkiss, and Song (2007). Note: The first private equity wave began in 1982 or 1983 and ended in 1989. The in 2007. in 2003 or 2004 and ended equity wave began

second

private

Next, we look at changes compare the ratio of equity used

in leverage buyout firm capital structures. We to finance leveraged buyouts in each time period and find that the share of equity used to finance leveraged buyouts was relatively constant in the firstwave at 10 percent to 15 percent and relatively constant in the second wave, but at roughly 30 percent. This striking increase in equity percentage from one era to the other is both a prediction of and consistent with the arguments in Kaplan

and Stein

that debt

investors offered overly favorable terms, particularly too much leverage, in the buyout wave of the 1980s. Valuations relative to a standardized measure of profits?EBITDA (earnings (1993)

interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization)?were higher in the recent were rates lower. Interest also changed. Figure 4 combines wave, but debt levels to forecast interest for the lever these factors by measuring the ratio of EBITDA before

of the aged buyouts of the two eras. This interest coverage ratio is a measure a transaction. ratio it of When this is that the lower, fragility buyout implies buyout ismore fragile, because the firm has less of a cushion from not being able tomeet interest payments. Figure 4 has two interesting implications. First, interest coverage ratios are higher in the recent wave, suggesting the deals are less fragile. Second, the cyclical pattern of the second wave remains. Coverage ratios are higher from

2001 to 2004 than in the periods before and after. Leveraged buyouts of the most recent wave also have been

associated

with

more

liberal repayment schedules and looser debt covenants. Consistent with this, we find patterns similar to (if not stronger than) those in Figure 4 when we factor in debt principal repayments. Demoriglu and James (2007) and Standard and Poor's (2008) also confirm that loan covenants became less restrictive at the end of the

recent

wave.

Figure 5 considers

cyclicality in private equity in one additional

way. It com

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

140

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

Figure 5 Standard

Value Less High-Yield Rates, 1985-2006 8e Poor's EBITDA/Enterprise " a measure stands cash ("EBITDA, of flow, for earnings before interest,taxes, depreciation, and amortization) 4.00% T

for S&P 500 companies less Merrill Lynch High-Yield Master Value EBITDA/Enterprise is the sum of market value of equity, book value of long (Cash Pay Only) Yield. Enterprise Value and short-term debt less cash and marketable securities.

Note: Median

to enterprise value for the Standard & Poor's pares the median ratio of EBITDA rate on to the interest 500, average high-yield bonds?the Merrill Lynch High Yield 1985 to 2006. In particular Figure 5 looks at from (cash pay bonds)?each year

measures the relation between operating earnings yield net of interest rate. This the cash flow generated per dollar of market value by the median company in the Standard & Poor's 500 and the interest rate on a highly leveraged financing. One can interpret thismeasure as the excess (or deficit) from financing the purchase of an entire company with high-yield bonds.

pattern is suggestive. A necessary (but not sufficient) condition for a on private equity boom to occur is for earnings yields to exceed interest rates true in in boom late-1980s boom and the This held the bonds. pattern high-yield The

earnings yields are less than interest rates from high-yield bonds, private equity activity tends to be lower. These patterns suggest that the debt used in a given leveraged buyout may be driven more by credit market conditions than by the relative benefits of leverage for of 2005 and 2006. When

operating

the firm. Axelson, Jenkinson, Str?mberg, and Weisbach (2008) find evidence consistent with this in a sample of large leveraged buyouts in the United States and Europe 1985-2007. They find that leverage is cross completed between to leverage in similar-size, same industry, public sec tionally unrelated to firm-specific factors that explain is unrelated leverage in public

firms and firms. In

stead, leveraged buyout capital structures are most strongly related to prevailing in leveraged buyouts debt market conditions at the time of the buyout. Leverage decreases

as

interest

rates

rise.

The

amount

of

leverage

available,

in turn,

seems

the firm. that the private equity fund pays to acquire that and Wofenzon find Richardson, (2007) private equity Similarly, Ljungqvist, funds accelerate their investment pace when interest rates are low. These results are to affect the amount

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity

consistent with the notion in the

private

that debt financing availability affects booms

141

and busts

market.

equity

patterns raise the question as towhy the borrowing of public firms does not follow the same credit market cycles. One potential is that public explanation firms are unwilling to take advantage of debt mispricing by increasing leverage, These

either

because

dislike

managers

or

debt

because

about high debt levels. A second explanation access

to credit

markets

because

are

they

market

public

investors

worry

is that private equity funds have better which

borrowers,

repeat

enables

to

them

build reputation with lenders. Recent papers by Ivashina and Kovner (2008) and Demiroglu and James (2007) suggest thatmore prominent private equity funds are to obtain

able

loans

cheaper the

is that

explanation

and

looser

covenants

debt

structures

compensation

than

of

private

incentives to take on more

Private Equity Fund Level The time series of private equity fund commitments a boom

by

the

studying we

First,

A

lenders. funds

equity

third

provide

debt than is optimal for the individual firm (Axelson, and Weisbach, forthcoming).

Jenkinson, Str?mberg,

to exhibit

other

and

bust

relation

pattern.

between

consider

the

In

this

section,

commitments

relation

earlier appear

this more

consider

closely

returns.

and

between

examined

we

private

equity

and

fundraising

subse

quent private equity fund returns. Table 3 presents illustrative regressions inwhich the dependent variable is the capital-weighted return to all private equity funds in a

raised

returns

year

vintage

Venture the

addition, their

to this as

refer

for U.S.

private

the

equity

returns

Economics

may

returns

have

the more

that

funds

not

does

from

comprise over time.

change

for

recent

Venture

all

is

private

are

probably

the as

of

are noisy funds.

equity

years

use

We

Economics

return measures

vintage

factor

(This

return."

year

"vintage

funds

2007 for vintage years 1984 to 2004. The

September because

year. We

particular

In

still active

and

because

unimportant

we obtain similar results when we eliminate all vintages after 1999.) As independent we

variables, the

ing

year

1 to 4 in Table

Regressions

vintage

subsequent

to

committed

capital

vintage

previous

and

use

private

to

relative

the

total

value

year

a

Including

the

of

3 indicate a strong negative returns.

in the

funds

equity

vintage

U.S.

and

year

stock

market.

relation between fundrais

time

trend

does

not

affect

the

this simple regression finding can only be considered illustrative of patterns, it suggests that inflows of capital into private equity funds in a

results. While broader

year

given

can

into

private

these

returns

fund

is associated

consider

regressions,

the the

with

lower

variables by

to which

extent

dependent

Venture

are

the

two

Economics.

that

regressions).

The

vintage

year

affect

is the annual

stock market returns

year's

previous

Note

returns

past

variable

the

annual

different from the vintage year return (which was previous

ten-

subsequent

to twelve

returns.

subsequent

private equity funds as a fraction of the U.S. independent as reported

the

during

these funds are active. It strongly suggests that an influx of capital

equity we

Next In

realized

explain

year period when

return

commitments.

capital

capital

from 1987 to 2006. The to

return

private to

the

again,

equity, private

the dependent

measures

to U.S.

committed

annual

equity

variable return

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

is

in the to all

142

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

Table 3 Relation

of Private Equity Returns

inUnited

and Fundraising

States

A

Panel

variable: Vintage year average internal rate of return to private equity (capital weighted) from 1984 to 2004

Dependent

equity commitments t stock market, Private equity commitments

Private

stock market,

(6.2) -32.60**

to

0.35

0.35

(7.2) -20.79*

(7.5)

(7.0)

(-1.6) -28.66**

(-2.4) to

-36.87***

t-\

(-2.2)

(-3.0)

equity commitments t+ t-\ stock market, Trend Private

Adjusted

0.31

0.31

Constant

(4)

(3)

(2)

(1)

to

-24.78***

(-1.0) 0.36

(-1.2) 0.28

R2

(-3.5) -0.002

-0.003

-0.004

Panel

-0.002 (-0.8) 0.41

(-0.8) 0.44

B

!variable: Private equity commitments toStockMarket, tfrom (as a fraction of the total value of theU.S. stockmarket)

1984 to 2007

(2)

(1) -0.091

Constant Annual

private equity return,

t-\

Annual

private equity return,

t-2

Trend

Adjusted

R2

-0.292

(-0.7) 0.007**

(-1.8) 0.008***

(2.1)

(2.6) 0.007**

0.031***

(2.4) 0.031***

(4.1) 0.40

(4.6) 0.50

internal rate of return is the average internal rate of return to U.S. equity vintage year a given year, according to Venture Economics. Mean vintage year internal rate raised in funds private equity are of return is 16.5 percent. Private equity commitments capital committed to U.S. private equity funds from Private Equity Analyst as a fraction of the total value of the U.S. stock market. Mean private equity return to all U.S. private return is the annual are 0.43 percent. Private equity annual commitments

Note: Private

equity funds according

to Venture Economics. Mean

parentheses. *** indicate *, **, and

statistical significance

raised

funds return

is a

in a

particular

geometric

year

average

annual

return is 18.6 percent.

at the 10, 5, and

over

the

of many

life of years

1 percent

the

of

errors are in

levels, respectively.

is, the vintage

fund?that

returns.

Standard

In

contrast,

the

year annual

return to private equity is the return to all private equity funds of different vintages in a

given Again,

calendar these

year. regressions

are meant

sions in panel B, capital commitments

only

to be

suggestive.

are positively and

In

these

two

regres

significantly related

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

to

StevenN Kaplan

lagged

private

returns?in

equity

returns. The positive fund

equity To

more

when

with a boom

Some

time

above

regressions,

when

any

private

to

follow

good

class.

returns

realized

factors.

cyclical

returns

fund

equity

to this asset

is committed

to decline

tend

equity

over

the

capital

seem

investors

words,

143

trend is consistent with significant secular growth in private

commitments

summarize

other

and Per Str?mberg

Capital

decline.

to decline

tend

to

commitments

These

are

patterns

private

consistent

and bust cycle in private equity.

Speculations

empirical evidence is strong that private equity activity creates economic value on average. We suspect that the increased investment by private equity firms The

in operational a

has

activity

will ensure

engineering

Because

future.

creates

equity

private substantial

permanent

that this result continues

economic

value,

we

believe

to hold

that

in the

private

equity

component.

However, the evidence also is strong that private equity activity is subject to boom and bust cycles, which are driven by recent returns as well as by the level of rates

interest particularly

to

relative true

for

and

earnings

larger

stock

market

substantially?when

seems

pattern

interest rates on buyout-related debt

is even

debt

buyout

This

transactions.

public-to-private

From the summer of 2007 intomid-2008,

increased

values.

at all. At

available

same

the

time,

corporate earnings have softened. In this setting, private equity activity is likely to be relatively low, particularly large public-to-private buyouts. Institutional investors are

to continue

likely

because

reported 2007,

September

to make private

Venture

not

have

Economics

reports

three years of 15.3 percent versus Standard 12.7

private

private

equity but

declined, equity

and Poor's

for

are

returns

a

at

time,

still

robust.

over

the

500 stock market

least, As

of

previous

returns of

percent.

likelihood

The robust

debt

while

not

expect

to private equity funds remain

that investors' commitments

markets

remain

unfavorable

to invest the capital committed. Given do

to

commitments

returns

that many

private

equity

will

create

pressure

for

private

firms

the fee structure of private equity funds, we firms

will

return

the money.

However,

these

patterns suggest that the structure of private equity deals will evolve. investments with less First, we suspect that private equity firms will make at least initially.While this change may reduce themagnitude of expected leverage, returns (and compensation),

change

risk-adjusted

as long as the private equity firms add value, itwill not

returns.

Second, we suspect that private equity firmswill be more likely to takeminority rather than buying the entire equity positions in public or private companies company. both

Private equity firms have experience

in venture

capital

investments

and

with minority equity investments,

in overseas

investments,

particularly

in

relatively new operational engineering capabilities of private equity firms may put them in a better position to supply minority investments than in the past, because private equity firms can provide additional value without having full Asia. The

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

144

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

control.

Moreover,

and

executives

top

boards

of

public

companies

may

have

an

and hedge fund increased demand for minority equity investments. Shareholder activism and hostility have increased substantially in recent years (Brav, Jiang, Partnoy, and Thomas et al., forthcoming). In the face ofthat hostility, private equity firms are likely to be perceived as partners or "white knights" by some chief officers

executive

and

boards.

Finally, what will happen private equity boom of 2005

to funds and

transactions completed in the recent It seems plausible that the ultimate

to mid-2007?

returns to private equity funds raised during these years will prove disappointing because firms are unlikely to be able to exit the deals from this period at valuations as high as the private equity firmspaid to buy the firms. It is also plausible that some

during the boom were less driven by the potential of operating and governance improvements, and more driven by the availability of debt financing, which also implies that the returns on these deals will be disap of the transactions undertaken

pointing. If and

when

private

returns

equity

decline,

private

commitments

equity

also

will decline. Lower returns to recent private equity funds are likely to coincide with some failed transactions, including debt defaults and bankruptcies. The relative magnitude of defaults and failed deals, however is likely to be lower than after the a downturn of roughly similar previous boom in the early 1990s, assuming magni returns for this period may disappoint, the transactions tude.While private equity of

the

recent

wave

had

higher

coverage

ratios

debt than those of the 1980s, which reduces will subsequently default.

and

looser

debt

the likelihood

covenants

on

their

that those companies

This research has been supported by theKauffman Foundation, theLynde and Harry Bradley Foundation, and theOlin Foundation throughgrants to theStigler Centerfor the Study of theEconomy and, theState, and by theCenterfor Research in SecurityPrices. We thankJimHines, Antoinette Schoar, Andrei Shleifer,JeremyStein, Timothy Taylor, and Mike

Wright for very helpful comments.

References 2008. "Cor Acharya, Viral, and Conor Kehoe. and Value Creation Evidence porate Governance from Private Equity." http://www.ecgi.org/ pdf. compet? tions/rof/files/Acharya_Kehoe_v5. Acharya, Viral, Julian Franks, and Henri Ser

or Bust."/oMr 2007. "Private Equity?Boom nal ofApplied Corporate Finance, 19(4): 44-53. Amess, Kevin, and Mike Wright. 2007a. "Bar

vaes.

barians

at the Gate?

Leveraged

Buyouts,

Private

and Jobs." http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/ 1034178. papers. cfm?abstract_id= Amess, Kevin, and Mike Wright. 2007b. "The

Equity

and Employment Effects of Leveraged in the UK." International Journal of the Buyouts Economics of Business, 14(2): 179-95. 1998. Andrade, Gregor, and Steven N. Kaplan.

Wage

"How

Dis (Not Economic Costly is Financial from Highly Leveraged Trans tress)? Evidence

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity

actions

That

Finance,

53(5):

Distressed."

Became

Journal

1443-94.

of

1990. and Thierry Wizman. Paul, Asquith, and Bondholder Re "Event Risk, Covenants, turns in Leveraged Buyouts." Journal Financial 195-213. Economics, 27(1): Axelson, Ulf, Tim Jenkinson, Per Str?mberg, and Michael Weisbach. 2008. "Leverage and Pric ing in Buyouts: An Empirical Analysis." http:// papers, ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id= 1027127. Axelson, Weisbach.

Ulf,

Per

Str?mberg,

and Michael

"Why Are Forthcoming. Buyouts The Financial Structure of Private Leveraged? Equity Funds." Journal ofFinance. 1992. "Beatrice: A Study in the Baker, George. Creation

Finance,

and Destruction

47(3):

of Value."

Journal

of

1081-1119.

Robin Greenwood, Baker, Malcolm, 2003. "The Maturity of Debt Wurgler.

and Jeff Issues and

in Bond Returns." Journal Variation 261-91. ofFinancial Economics, 70(2): and JeffWurgler. 2000. "The Baker, Malcolm, Stock Equity Share in New Issues and Aggregate Predictable

Returns."

2219-57. Journal ofFinance, 55(5): Frederik L?once, Schlingemann, Bargeron Rene Stulz, and Chad Zutter. 2007. "Why Do Pri to Public vate Acquirers Pay So Little Compared Fisher College of Business Working Acquirers?" Paper 2007-03-011. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/ - 980066 papers.cfm?abstract_id and Sara Grubb, C?as, Michael Bergstr?m, Jonsson. 2007. "The Operating Impact of Buy outs in Sweden: A Study of Value Creation." Journal ofPrivate Equity, 11(1): 22-39.

Shleifer, and Robert Bhagat, Sanjai, Andrei in the 1980's: 1990. "Hostile Takeovers Vishny. Brook The Return to Corporate Specialization." ings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, 1990, Special Issue, pp. 1-84. David Sraer, and David Quentin, 2008. "Do Leveraged Buyouts Appro Rents? Evidence from French priate Worker HEC Paris Data." Working (Groupe Paper,

Boucly, Thesmar.

HEC). Brav, Al?n, Wei Jiang, Frank Partnoy, and "The Returns to Randall Thomas. Forthcoming. Fund Activism." Journal ofFinance. Hedge Cao, JerryX., and Josh Lerner. 2007. "The Per formance of Reverse Leveraged Buyouts." http:// = papers, ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id 937801. and Oguzhan Karakas. Francseca, Cornelli, Gover "Private Equity and Corporate 2008. nance: Do LBOs Have More Effective Boards?" http://www.ecgi.org/competitions/rof/files/ Do%20LBOs%20have%20more%20effective %20boards,%20(Cornelli,%20Karakas).pdf.

145

Donald Cumming, Douglas, Siegel, and Mike 2007. "Private Equity, Leveraged Wright. Buy outs and Governance." Journal of Corporate Finance,

439-60.

13(4):

Ron Steven, John Haltiwanger, 2008. Josh Lerner, and Javier Miranda. U.S. Census Equity and Employment." Davis,

Center for Economic

Jarmin, "Private Bureau

Studies Paper CES-WP-08-07.

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm? 1107175. abstract_id= and Chris James. 2007. Cem, Demiroglu, "Lender Control and the Role of Private Equity in Buyout Financing." http:// Group Reputation www.bi.no/OsloFiles/ccgr/Demiroglu_James.pdf. 2008. Gadiesh, Orit, and Hugh MacArthur.

Lessons From Private Equity Any Company Can Use. Business School Press. Boston, MA: Harvard Gertner, Rob, and Steven N. "The Value Maximizing Board."

http://papers. 10563.

ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract.id=:: Paul, and Josh Lerner. Gompers,

Use

of Covenants:

An Empirical

1996.

Kaplan.

1996.

"The

of Ven

Analysis

ture Partnership Agreements." Journal of Law and Economics, 39(2): 463-98. 1998. "What Paul, and Josh Lerner. Gompers,

Drives

Venture

Capital

Fundraising?"

Brookings

Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics: pp, 149-92.

1998,

and Josh Lerner. 2000. Paul, Gompers, Deals? The "Money Chasing Impact of Fund Inflows on Private Equity Valuations." Journal of Financial Economics, 55(2): 281-325. Graham, John. 2003. "Taxes and Corporate Finance: 16(4):

A Review."

Review

of Financial

Studies,

1075-1129.

and Oliver Hart. 1980. Grossman, Sanford, "Takeover Bids, the Free-rider Problem, and the Bell Journal of Eco Theory of the Corporation." nomics, 11(1): Guo, Song.

42-64.

and Weihong Shouron, Edith Hotchkiss, 2007. "Do Buyouts (Still) Create Value?"

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm? 1108808. abstract_id= Hamilton, and Richard Rates ery 1920-2005." tors Sendee

David, Praveen Cantor. 2006.

Varma, Sharon Ou, "Default and Recov

of Bond Corporate Special Comment. Moody's Global Credit Research.

Issuers, Inves

Donald and Mike Harris, Richard, Siegel, Wright. 2005. "Assessing the Impact of Manage ment Buyouts on Economic Efficiency: Plant level Evidence from the United Kingdom." The Review ofEconomics

and Statistics, 87(1): 148-53. and Steven N. Kaplan. Holmstr?m, Bengt, 2003. "The State of U.S. Corporate Governance: What's Right and What's Wrong?" Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 15(3): 8-20. Holthausen,

Robert,

and David

Larcker.

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

1996.

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

146

"The

Financial

aged

Buyouts." 293-332. 42(3):

Performance Journal

of Reverse

of Financial

Lever

Economics,

and Anna Kovner. 2008. Ivashina, Victoria, "The Private Equity Advantage: Buy Leveraged out Firms and Relationship Banking." http:// = papers, ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id = l&srcabs= 1017857&rec 1009281. 1986. "Agency Costs of Free Jensen, Michael. Finance and Takeovers." Cash Flow, Corporate American Economic Review, 76(2): 323-29. 1989. "Eclipse of the Public Jensen, Michael. Business Review, 67(5): Harvard Corporation." 61-74. 1990. and Kevin J. Murphy. Jensen, Michael, Incen "Performance Pay and Top Management tives." Journal ofPolitical Economy, 98(2): 225-64.

Steven N. 1989a. "Management Buy Kaplan, on Taxes as a Source of Value." outs: Evidence Journal

611-32. ofFinance, 44(3): Steven N. 1989b. "The Effects of Man

Kaplan,

on Operating Performance agement Buyouts and Value." Journal ofFinancial Economics, 24(2): 217-54. Steven N. 1991. "The Staying Power Kaplan, of Leveraged Buy-outs." Journal ofFinancial Eco nomics, 29(2): 287-313. of Steven N. 1997. "The Evolution Kaplan,

We Are All Henry Governance: Corporate Kravis Now." Journal ofPrivate Equity, 1(1): 7-14. Steven N. 2005. "SunGard Data Sys Kaplan, Graduate of Chicago tems." Case, University

U.S.

School

of Business.

http://faculty.chicagogsb.

edu/steven.kaplan/research/tm/tm.html. Steven N., and Antoinette Kaplan, 2005. Capital 1823.

Schoar.

and "Private Equity Returns: Persistence 1791? Flows." Journal of Finance, 60(4):

Steven N., and Jeremy Stein. 1993. Kaplan, "The Evolution of Buyout Pricing and Financial Structure in the 1980s." Quarterly Journal ofEco nomics, 108(2):

313-57.

and Wan Schoar, Lerner, Josh, Antoinette 2007. "Smart Investors, Foolish Choices: Wang. Puzzle." Jour The Limited Partner Performance nal ofFinance, 62(2): 731-64. and Per Sorensen, Lerner, Josh, Morten 2008. "Private Equity and Long Run Str?mberg. Investment: The Case of Innovation." http://

papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id= 1088543. Frank R., and Donald Lichtenberg, Siegel. 1990. "The Effects of Leveraged Buyouts on Pro ductivity and Related Aspects of Firm Behavior." Journal

165-194. ofFinancial Economics, 27(1): Alexander, Matthew Richardson,

Ljungqvist,

and Daniel

Wolfenzon.

"The

2007.

of Buyout Funds: Theory

Behavior

Investment

and Evidence."

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm? = 972640. abstract_id Marais, Laurentius, Abbie Smith. 1989. Private on Senior

Securities."

Economics,

155-91.

23(1):

and Schipper, Effects of Going Journal ofFinancial

Katherine "Wealth

and Ayako Yasuda. 2007. Metrick, Andrew, of Private Equity Funds." Working "Economics Business School. http://papers. Paper, Wharton ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=996334. 1994. "Efficiency Gains in Unsuc Ofek, Elie.

cessful Management 637-54.

Buyouts." Journal ofFinance,

49(2):

and Oliver Gottschalg. Ludovic, Phalippou, "Performance of Private Equity Forthcoming. Funds." Revieiv ofFinancial Studies. 2007. "If Private Equity Sized Pozen, Robert. Your

Up

Business."

Harvard

Business

Review,

78-87. 85(11): Private Equity Analyst. 2008. 2007 Review and 2008 Outlook. New York: Dow Jones. 1990. "The Structure and Sahlman, William.

of Venture Capital Organizations." Governance 473-521. Journal ofFinancial Economics, 27(2): Service Employees International Union. 2007. Behind

theBuyout http://www.behindthebuyouts.

org/. 1990. "Capital Ownership Struc Smith, Abbie. ture and Performance: The Case of Manage

ment

Buyouts."

Journal

143-64. 27(1): and Poor's. Standard Review

of Financial

2008.

Economics,

Leveraged Lending

1Q08.

http://www.lcdcomps.com/pg/ research/us_research.html. Stein, Jeremy. 2005. "Why Are Most Funds

Open-End?

Competition

trage." Quarterly 247-72. of

Str?mberg, Private

Journal

Per. 2008. Equity."

and

the Limits of Arbi

of Economics,

120(1):

"The New Demography http://www.sifr.org/

pelle.html. Swensen, David. 2000. Pioneering Portfolio Man to Institu agement: An Unconventional Approach tional Investment. New York: Free Press. Weir, Charlie, Peter Jones, and Mike Wright. Private Eq 2007. "Public to Private Transactions, in the UK: An Empirical uity and Performance Analysis

of the Impact of Going

Private." http://

papers, ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_ id= 1138616. 1996. "Higher Market Valu Yermack, David. with a Small Board of Direc ation of Companies to ys.""Journal ofFinancial Economics, 40(2): 185 211.

This content downloaded from 129.79.119.131 on Tue, 18 Aug 2015 18:29:11 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions