Cyclical Patterns of Employment, Utilization and Profitability

Report 3 Downloads 61 Views
University of Massachusetts - Amherst

ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst Economics Department Working Paper Series

Economics

2010

Cyclical Patterns of Employment, Utilization and Profitability Ben Zipperer University of Massachusetts - Amherst, [email protected]

Peter Skott University of Massachusetts - Amherst, [email protected]

Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarworks.umass.edu/econ_workingpaper Part of the Economics Commons Zipperer, Ben and Skott, Peter, "Cyclical Patterns of Employment, Utilization and Profitability" (2010). Economics Department Working Paper Series. Paper 96. http://scholarworks.umass.edu/econ_workingpaper/96

This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics at ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economics Department Working Paper Series by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst. For more information, please contact [email protected].

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Working Paper

Cyclical patterns of employment, utilization and profitability by Ben Zipperer and Peter Skott Working Paper 2010-02

UNIVERSITY OF MASSACHUSETTS AMHERST

Cyclical patterns of employment, utilization and protability Ben Zipperer



and Peter Skott



February 27, 2010

Abstract The interaction between income distribution, accumulation, employment and the utilization of capital is central to macroeconomic models in the `heterodox' tradition. This paper examines the stylized pattern of these variables using US data for the period after 1948. We look at the trends and cycles in individual time series and examine the bivariate cycical patterns among the variables.

JEL classication: E12, E32, O41 Key words: growth, business cycles, aggregate demand, instability, income distribution, utilization rate, investment function, pricing. ∗ Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts Amherst, MA 01003, USA; [email protected]. † Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts Amherst, MA 01003, USA; [email protected].

1

Introduction

The `heterodox' tradition in macroeconomics contains a wide range of models. Kaleckian models treat the utilization rate as an accommodating variable, both in the short and the long run. Goodwin's celebrated formalization of Marx, by contrast, take the utilization rate as xed and looks at the interaction between employment and distribution. Distribution is also central to Kaldorian and Robinsonian theories which, like Goodwin, endogenize the prot share and take the utilization rate as structurally determined in the long run but, like the Kaleckians, view short-run variations in utilization as an intrinsic part of the cycle. The dierences in these and other areas are important, and this diversity of views on core issues is no cause for celebration. Real-world economies dier widely, of course, and appropriate models will reect these dierences.

One would not want to use the same model to analyze advanced, labor-

constrained economies and dual economies with large (hidden) unemployment.

But an

attempt should be made to resolve fundamental disagreements on the dynamics of accumulation, income distribution and utilization rates in an advanced capitalist economy. Theoretical and empirical work is needed to evaluate the theories and help create a coherent and convincing alternative to the existing orthodoxy. This paper makes no attempt to address the theoretical issues.

Instead, we explore

US data on some of the variables that most, if not all heterodox macroeconomic theories consider important: utilization.

employment rates, prot shares, accumulation rates, and capacity

1 The paper complements and extends recent studies of US cycles by Barbosa-

Filho and Taylor (2006) and Mohun and Veneziani (2008).

Both of these contributions

use the Goodwin model as their theoretical framework; the former focusing exclusively on oscillations in prots and utilization, and the latter on prots and employment. The paper is in 5 sections. Section 2 discusses some general data issues. Trends and cycles of the variables are presented in section 3, and section 4 examines bivariate cyclical patterns among the variables. A nal section summarizes the main ndings.

2

Data

Benchmark versions of the heterodox models are typically cast in terms of closed economies without a public sector, and a one-good assumption implies that sectoral dierences are taken to be insignicant. In short, the models describe a pure capitalist economy. Abstract models of this kind can be very useful.

They serve to highlight particular

issues and can be used to examine the logic of mechanisms that may operate within the more complex reality of real-world economies too. But questions arise if one wants to take the simple models to the data. It is hard to evaluate the models since their predictions can be negated by other inuences  explosive cycles for instance may be tamed by the

1

Theoretical issues are discussed in a companion paper, Skott and Zipperer (2010). See also Skott (2010).

1

inuence of public policy  and it may not even be obvious which data should be used as the empirical counterparts to the theoretical variables. Our approach in this paper is to look at sectors that, according to the theories themselves, should conform to the behavioral assumptions. In practice, this criterion suggests a focus on prot shares, accumulation and capacity utilization for the corporate business sector.

Employment, however, is dierent.

The state of the labor market  the size of

the reserve army of labor  is important because it aects the balance of power between workers and capital, and the relevant measure is the average economy-wide employment rate. Other questions concern the precise denition of the variables. How for instance should one treat taxes in the calculation of prot shares? The answers to many questions of this kind depend on the precise purpose of the analysis.

There may be no uniquely correct

answers and even if there is, data limitations restrict what can be done in practice. Given these problems, the best one can do may be to be clear about the denition of the chosen indicators and to test, when possible, the sensitivity of the observed patterns to changes in the choice of indicators. We are interested in cyclical uctuations as well as long-term trends, and high-frequency data therefore are desirable. US employment and utilization data are available monthly, but corporate-sector prot data are published on a quarterly basis and unless noted, all data below are quarterly averages. Data are seasonally adjusted by the reporting agency, and we assume that these adjustments adequately correct for seasonal eects. The sample begins in the rst quarter of 1948, the earliest available US employment rates, and ends in the nal quarter of 2008, the last full year of available data at the time of writing.

2

In addition to actual data observations, we smooth the data to construct a short-term and a long-run trend. The smoothing procedure employs the Hodrick-Prescott (1997) lter with smoothing parameters 6.25 and 129,600 for short and long-run trends respectively. While the parameter choice is largely arbitrary  any `small' and `large' numbers would be suitable for our descriptive analysis  these specic short- and long-run parameters are recommended by Ravn and Uhlig (2002) for business cycle analysis of annual and monthly data, respectively. Our smaller-than-usual smoothing parameter for the short-run trend is intended to lter out extreme peaks only, leaving considerable quarter-to-quarter variation. Our higher-than-usual smoothing parameter for the long-run trend reects our eort to describe a long-term variation over decades. Because the actual 1948q1 and 2008q4 observations may bias the constructed endpoints of the long-term trend, we restrict the long-term trend to 1953-2001. That is, after creating the ltered series, we drop the years 1948-1952 and 2002-2008 from the constructed long-term trend, beginning and ending the long-term trend close to the 1953q2 and 2001q1 NBER business cycle peaks.

2

All US data in this paper were collected in September 2009. The US national accounts data used include the `nal' 2008q4 gures for prots and output, as well as the BEA's July 2009 comprehensive revision. OECD data were collected in December 2009.

2

3

Trends and cycles

3.1 Prot shares To measure the prot share

π,

we use the surplus and compensation subcategories of

quarterly value added, net of depreciation, in the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA).

3 The largest private sector in the NIPA

tables for which quarterly compensation and operating surplus delineations are available is domestic corporate business. As a share of the total business sector, corporate business net value added rose during 1948-2008, from 57 percent in 1948q1 to 64 percent in 2008q4;

4 Although

as a share of total GDP it remained roughly constant at about 50 percent.

to some extent dictated by data availability, the use of corporate sector data can also, as noted above, be justied by a cleaner application of the theories to corporate than to noncorporate business. Net value added (gross value added net of depreciation) is fully decomposed into taxes on production, labor compensation, and net operating surplus.

In the BEA national

accounts, net operating surplus includes taxes on corporate income (which are dierent than production taxes). How one treats taxes can therefore in principle produce dierent proxies for the prot share. For example, three candidate series are

π= π∗ = π0 =

net surplus + production taxes net surplus + production taxes + compensation net surplus net surplus + compensation net surplus - corporate income taxes net surplus - corporate income taxes + compensation

Over 1948-2008, the means for

π, π∗,

and

π0

are, respectively, 0.29, 0.21, and 0.15. The

decision to omit or include production taxes yields series with virtually identical variation: the correlation coecient between

π

and

π∗

is

0.98.

In contrast, the treatment of corpo-

rate income taxes yields series with dierent long-term variation (but similar short-term uctuations). Figure 1 shows the actual quarterly evolution of

π

and

π0,

as well as their

short- and long-run Hodrick-Prescott ltered trends. Focusing on the prot share inclusive of all taxes, prots accounted for one-third of output at their peak in the early 1950s. A substantial redistribution towards labor income followed, and the prot share temporarily fell below one-quarter around the onset of the 1980 recession before swinging upwards again in the 1980s and 1990s.

Using the prot

0 share π exclusive of all taxes, the long redistribution toward labor after the 1950s fails 0 to occur. The long-term series for π remained around 14% until around the 1980s, after which the share of prots began to increase substantially.

3 4

See http://www.bea.gov/national/nipaweb/index.asp See BEA NIPA Tables 1.3.5 and 1.14.

3

These long-term movements

capture most of the dierence between the two series. Although the correlation coecient between actual quarterly observations for

π

and

π0

is 0.42, deviations of each series from

its long-term trend correlate at 0.92. In simple models prot maximizing markups over cost are unaected by a change in the tax rate on prots, and for many purposes it will be reasonable to include taxes with

5 In section 4 unless otherwise noted we therefore take the prot share 6 sum of the surplus and taxes, divided by value added.

prots.

FIGURE 1 - US quarterly prot shares

π

and

π0;

π

to be the

actual, and short-term and long-term

trends A potentially large problem with the above denition of the prot share concerns its treatment of executive pay, which NIPA tables include as compensation.

Executive

compensation has increased dramatically and arguably a large part of this increase should be included with prots. Our measure of the prot share fails to do this and may give a misleading picture of the trend in protability, especially for the period after the 1980s. Krueger (1999) attempts to account for this issue by modifying the NIPA data using a compensation series derived from the Bureau of Labor Statistics Employment Cost Index (ECI)  whose data exclude jobs in which employees have a signicant role in setting their own wages  which grew more slowly over 1988-1995 than labor's share of income in the NIPA.

7 . After using the ECI data to modify the NIPA-based prot share, Krueger nds

that instead of growing only 0.6 percentage points over 1988-1995, the modied prot share grew somewhere between 1.9 and 4.6 percentage points, depending on the nature of the adjustment. A similar adjustment to our data would steepen the most recent long-term rise in the prot share, although it is unclear,

a priori, what impact this adjustment would

have on the cyclical component of the prot share around its trend.

3.2 Utilization rates We use the Federal Reserve capacity utilization series for manufacturing.

The Federal

Reserve also publishes a capacity utilization series for the total industrial sector but this series only exists since 1967.

8

The manufacturing series may be more reliable and the

movements in the total industrial series closely match those for the manufacturing series. The average over 1967-2008 of the former is 81.3% compared to 80.1% for the latter, and the correlation coecient between the two series is 0.99. The Federal Reserve manufacturing series is monthly and seasonally adjusted, and we take quarterly averages for the 19482008 period. Over the period, utilization uctuates strongly with extreme values above 90

5

The invariance of the optimal markup is subject to qualiations. Consumer loyalty or other intertemporal elements in demand can make it optimal for a rm to vary its markup in response to uctuations in the tax rate. 6 See lines 4, 7, and 8 of NIPA Table 1.14. 7 The ECI data begin in 1975: http://www.bls.gov/news.release/eci.tn.htm 8 See Shapiro (1989) for a review of how the Federal Reserve calculates capacity and utilization. 4

percent and below 70 percent (Figure 2). In January 1986 the Federal Reserve switched from SIC to NAICS industry classication, possibly introducing a discontinuity that may aect statistical analysis. We ignore this complication. FIGURE 2 - US quarterly manufacturing utilization rate

u; actual, and short-term and

long-term trends

3.3 Accumulation and capital capacity To approximate changes in the capital stock, there are two candidate data series for the

9

US: Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) net xed assets , and the Federal Reserve (Fed)

10 Both series are available for the manufacturing sector. industrial capacity index.

The capacity index measures the greatest level of output each plant ... can maintain within the framework of a realistic work schedule. monthly. To calculate quarterly capacity changes

ˆ K

11

The capacity series is published

from the monthly published data, we

calculate the percent dierence between index values three months apart: fourth quarter

ˆ K

is the percent dierence between December and September values; rst quarter

ˆ K

is

calculated from March's index value and the previous year's December value. The average quarterly growth rate of manufacturing capacity was about 0.9 percent between 1948-2008. The growth rate generally fell over the period, with large peaks in the mid-to-late 1960s and mid-to-late 1990s. The same 1986 SIC to NAICS industrial classication change mentioned above for the utilization series may also aect the capacity series, a complication we ignore. FIGURE 3 - Quarterly Fed-based

ˆ; K

actual, and short-term and long-term trends

While the Fed series is monthly, the BEA data are annual. This is a serious disadvantage for the analysis of cyclical patterns and there may also be other reasons to prefer the Fed data. Heterodox models usually assume a xed coecient production function and a constant rate of depreciation. If these assumptions are satised, indicators of production capacity (the Fed data) and capital stock (BEA) will coincide, if correctly measured. If the assumptions are relaxed, however, the two indicators can deviate, and the economic argument behind the standard investment functions concerns the desired increase in capacity. For some purposes, at least, the Fed data therefore may be preferable on theoretical grounds (as well as because of their high frequency). The BEA series is based on the end-of-year capital stock, and we calculate its annual

n − 1.

To

determine annual changes using the Fed series, we calculate the rate of change in year

n as

changes in year

n

as the percent dierence between values in years

n

and

9 See the manufacturing industry entry in BEA Table 4.2 of non-residential xed assets: http://www.bea.gov/national/FA2004/ 10 See http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/G17/caputl.htm. 11 Corrado and Mattey (1997) describe how the Federal Reserve capacity series is constructed. See also Shapiro (1989).

5

the percent dierence between December values in years

n and n−1.

Figure 4 shows actual

annual rates of change for the Fed and BEA series, as well as their smoothed, long-term trends. For the long-term trends of these annual data, we use a smoothing parameter of 1000, which results in long-term annual rates of change similar to the long-term annual

12

rates of change from quarterly data.

Over 1948-2008, the annual Fed-based rate of capacity changes average about 3.5%, whereas the annual BEA accumulation rates average 2.7%. The two annual series generally move together, with a correlation coecient of 0.74, indicating some support for using xedcoecient production functions. Signicant dierences between the series occur in 19491950 and 1958-1960, when the Fed series exceed the BEA series by about 2-3 percentage points, and in 1996-1999, when the gap is about 3-5 percentage points. In 1974, the BEA series is more than 2 percentage points larger than the Fed series. Since 1982, the Fedbased measure has exceeded that for the BEA, a trend consistent with increasing reliance on computer-based technology. For example, the the large relative run-up in the Fed-series in the 1990s may be viewed in terms of rms realizing productivity gains from computer equipment. The BEA series may show small increases in the capital stock because prices for computers, relative to other machinery, fell dramatically over that period. FIGURE 4 - Annual Fed-based and BEA-based

ˆ; K

actual and long-term trend

3.4 Employment rates We measure the employment rate

e

as one minus the seasonally adjusted unemployment

rate from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) Current Population Survey (CPS).

13 This

economy-wide denition of the employment rate hides all regional, sectoral and skill-specic dierences in labor market conditions.

The implied BLS measure of movements in the

total labor force is in line with common simplifying assumptions of a constant growth rate in the labor force, but the denition avoids complications from historical shifts in the US employment-to-population ratio that may have been endogenous (for example due to female labor market entry). As shown in Figure 5, the employment rate peaked at more than 97 percent in the early 1950s and dropped to less than 90 percent during 1982-1983. Over 1948-2008, however, it rarely escaped the 92-96 percent range. In a comparison of US-Census-based and BLS Current Population Survey-based employment rates, Schmitt and Baker (2006) noted that the BLS may increasingly be understating the unemployment rate around the order of several tenths of a percentage point. We ignore this complication, although accounting for it would slightly lower the most recent end of the long-term employment trend.

12

Using the same long-term smoothing parameter we used for quarterly data on the annual data would result in an approximately linear long-term series. 13 See http://stats.bls.gov/data/.

6

FIGURE 5 - US quarterly employment rate

e;

actual, and short-term and long-term

trends

3.5 Trends The considerable short-term variation in the utilization series may overshadow relatively modest long-term movements. Figure 6 graphs the percentage-point dierence between the mean and long-run Hodrick-Prescott values for the prot share, utilization rate, employment rate and the annual accumulation rate. The span between maximum and minimum long-run dierences from the mean of the employment rate is modest at 2.7 percentage points.

The span of deviations from the mean is similar for both prot shares and uti-

lization rates, 4.4 percentage points for the prot share and 5.7 percentage points for utilization. But the mean values are dierent and the relative long-term variation for the prot share is much larger than for the utilization rate: the span between the maximum and minimum of the proportional deviation from the mean is 2.8 percentage points for the employment rate, 7.0 percentage points for the utilization rate, and 15.6 percentage points for the prot share. Annual Fed-based accumulation rates average about 3.6 percent, and the span of absolute dierences from this mean is about 2.0 percentage points (corresponding to a span of proportional dierences of 53.1 percentage points). FIGURE 6 - Dierence between the US mean and long-run trend, for utilization, employment, prot shares, and quarterly accumulation rate

4

Bivariate cyclical patterns

4.1 Employment - protability Figure 7 contains two time-connected scatterplots of US employment rates and prot shares. Dots in the top panel are actual quarterly observations in the

(e, π)-plane.

The

bottom panel is a slightly smoothed version using the short-run HP trend described above. Each rst-quarter observation is dated with its year. Line segments between the quarterly observations merely help to illustrate the time orientation. FIGURE 7 - US actual and smoothed

(e, π)-plane

cycles

The clockwise loops follow National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) business

14 The cycles are most easily distinguished in the bottom panel containing smoothed

cycles.

data, and this panel also shows the long-run variation discussed in the previous subsection. Until the early 1970s the center of the loops shifted vertically as the prot share fell while

14

See http://www.nber.org/cycles.html.

7

employment remained above 93 percent. The leftward shift towards higher unemployment over the 1970s and 1980s occurred while the prot share remained below 30 percent. The 1980s began a shift in

e

and

π

to the northeast, towards greater employment rates and

higher prot shares. The salient clockwise cycles in the smoothed data are not an artifact of the ltering process. In the actual quarterly data, the prot share moves procyclically: the correlation between it and the employment rate is 0.51, but the correlation between the lags of the prot share and the current employment rate is stronger (for instance, a two year lag of has a 0.66 correlation with

e).

produce clockwise cycles in the

π

Oscillations in one of these variables therefore necessarily

(e, π)-plane.

Figure 8 - Deviation of US employment and prot shares from their long term trends in the

(e, π)-plane.

To get a clearer picture of the cyclical element, we follow the approach of Mohun and Veneziani (2008, 2009) and examine the deviations of the actual quarterly observations of

(e, π)

from their long-run trend.

This approach may be appropriate in particular if

the long-term variation in employment, prot shares, and utilization reect structural or institutional shifts in the economy (e.g., changes in the bargaining power of workers through a rise or fall in unionization) that are unrelated to the short cycles. Figure 8 displays the deviations. The separate panels correspond to NBER-dated peakto-peak business cycles, but we include observations from one year after the second peak to account for

(e, π)

cycles that `complete' after the NBER cycle has ended  for example,

the cycle in the 1960s. All of the deviation-based cycles are qualitatively well-structured and clockwise-oriented, except for the short cycle starting around the beginning of the 1980q1 recession.

4.2 Employment - utilization and utilization - protability cycles Similar clockwise cycles exist in the 10.

(e, u)- and (u, π)-planes,

as displayed in Figures 9 and

The amplitudes of the uctuations (like the period length) dier across cycles, and

there are signicant dierences in the average amplitude of the variables. The employment rate and prot shares typically vary by less than 6 percentage points over a cycle, whereas utilization varies by up to 15-20 percentage points. Figure 9 - Deviation of US employment and utilization from their long term trends in the

(e, u)-plane.

Figure 10 - Deviation of US utilization and prot shares from their long term trends in the

(u, π)-plane.

8

4.3 Other patterns Yˆ .

Visibly regular cycles are also present when considering output growth

To calculate

output growth, we use the quarterly growth rate of real net (of depreciation) value added for the corporate business sector. Since BEA does not publish real output or a deator for the overall corporate sector, to adjust for ination, we use the deator implied by the BEA series on real and nominal output of the nonnancial business sector.

15 This measure

of quarterly real output growth averaged 0.9 percent over 1948-2008, varying widely until the 1960s, after which it mostly remained within the range of -2 to 4 percent. Clockwise rotations appear in

(e, Yˆ )-, (π, Yˆ )-, and (u, Yˆ )-planes for the slightly- smoothed, short-term

trends for these variables (see Figure 11). Cycles, nally, seem to exist with quarterly Fed accumulation rates

ˆ K

plotted against employment, prot shares, and utilization, but their

orientations are not as consistent (Figure 12). Figure 11 - Smoothed cycles in the

(e, Yˆ )-, (π, Yˆ )-,

Figure 12 - Smoothed cycles in the

ˆ -, (π, K) ˆ -, (e, K)

and

and

(u, Yˆ )-planes. ˆ -planes. (u, K)

4.4 Robustness The cycles are robust to modications of the underlying data. For example, cycles exist regardless of choosing either the Fed's manufacturing or the total industry utilization series. Data variations like these result in only trivial dierences because of the high correlation between the alternative and original data series. Using either the BEA-based and or Fedbased annual accumulation series produces similarly- oriented cycles.

The existence of

cycles is not altered by dening the numerator of the prot share  the surplus  to be inclusive or net of taxes on production or corporate prots, as well as including or omitting these taxes in the denominator of the prot share. As noted above, this is likely due to the high correlation between the prot share series. We also examined the implications of changing the method for constructing utilization data by looking at output deviations from a smoothed output series. Taking the ratio of corporate value added to its Hodrick-Prescott long-run trend yields a utilization series that is qualitatively dierent than the Fed series other, the output-based

u0

u.

u0

While the two series still track each

contains dierent variation: the correlation coecient for

u and

u0 is 0.63, as opposed to 0.99 between the Fed's two series. While using the output based0 series u may yield dierent results for a more detailed econometric study, similar cycles emerge in

(u, π)- and (u0 , π)-planes.

Figure 13 illustrates these cycles using the short-term,

slightly smoothed series. FIGURE 13 - Smoothed cycles in Fed-based

15

See NIPA Table 1.14, lines 19 and 42. 9

(u, π)-

and output-based

(u0 , π)-planes.

4.5 Other countries The existence of cycles in prot, employment, and utilization spaces are not peculiar to the US economy. As Harvie (2000), Mohun and Veneziani (2009), and others have observed, European economies can exhibit prot-share/employment rate cycles.

Using quarterly

OECD data, we conrm the existence of cycles using utilization rates as well. With one exception, we limited our sample to those countries in the OECD.Stat Database

16 with

at least two decades of consecutive quarterly surplus, employment, and utilization data: the US, Belgium, Canada, Great Britain, France, Italy, the Netherlands, and Spain. The exception is Japan which was included because of its size and importance, and for which

17 Data

the OECD has employment and utilization series but no quarterly surplus data.

availability causes the sample period to vary by country, but in general the sample covers the 1980s into the 2000s. FIGURE 14 - Quarterly

e, π , u

for OECD countries

Figure 14 shows actual quarterly employment, prot share, and utilization series for the

18 Utilization rates largely uctuate around 80%, with Japan's utiliza-

sample countries.

tion being much higher in the late 1960s and early 1970s. The highest country average is France's at 84.4%, and the lowest average is Italy's at 75.9%. Prot shares oscillate between one-quarter and one-third for most countries, except for Italy and Spain, where shares average about 42.7% and 44.9%, respectively. There is considerable variation among countries' employment rates. Japan's employment rate was the highest in most of the period but fell below the US and the Netherlands in the mid-to-late 1990s. Spain's employment rate is usually the lowest and the most volatile, at extremes uctuating more than 4 percentage points from its long-term trend. Cycles for these countries are generally present but not as cleanly observed as in the US data.

This is not surprising.

Smaller countries are much more aected by foreign

trade, and most of the countries have public sectors that are substantially larger than in the US. Hence, cyclical patterns that arise from the private-sector interaction between accumulation, output and pricing decisions will not have the same regularity in these countries. Figures 15-20 depict the patterns for two countries, France and Spain. contains deviations of

(u, π)

from its long-term trend in France.

16

Figure 15

For the sample time

http://stats.oecd.org For all countries, utilization rates are for the manufacturing sector, except in the cases of Canada and Japan, which report total industrial utilization. All rates are capacity utilization rates (measured 0% to 100%), except in the case of Japan, which reports a utilization index with a base year of 2005. To convert Japan's index to a rate comparable to other countries' rates, we arbitrarily assume that the 2005 capacity utilization rate value for Japan is 80.0%. 18 There are cross-country correlations between the business cycles and utilization rates sometime track each other across countries and sometimes not  for example, Great Britain's series correlates well with the US but not with France. 17

10

period, France's clockwise cycles in

(u, π)

correspond well to the country's rst three

19 Arguably there is no well-dened cycle present for the 1998q2-2000q4

business cycles.

peak-to-peak, and a relatively rough clockwise cycle appears for the 2000q4-2008q1 cycle. Similarly, gures 16 and 17 show for France that clockwise cycles usually, but not always, exist in

(e, π)-

and

(e, u)-planes.

FIGURE 15 - Deviation of utilization and prot shares in France from their long term trends in the

(u, π)-plane

FIGURE 16 - Deviation of employment and prot shares in France from their long term trends in the

(e, π)-plane

Figure 17 - Deviation of employment and utilization in France from their long term trends in the

(e, u)-plane

Spain exhibits clear clockwise

(u, π)

cycles in the 1983q4-1989q2 and 1991q4-1995q1

peak-to-peak business cycles. Less clear are whether there exist

(u, π)

cycles during the

1979q3-1983q4 and 1991q4-1995q1 business cycles. The 1995q1-1998q2 period exhibits a clear counter-clockwise cycle.

Within the 1998q2-2008q1 cycle, there appear to be two

cycles, the rst counter-clockwise and the second clockwise. Figures 19 and 20 show mixed results for clockwise cycles in the

(e, π)-

and

(e, u)-planes.

FIGURE 18 - Deviation of utilization and prot shares in Spain from their long term trends in the

(u, π)-plane

FIGURE 19 - Deviation of employment and prot shares in Spain from their long term trends in the

(e, π)-plane

Figure 20 - Deviation of employment and utilization in Spain from their long term trends in the

(e, u)-plane

Prot shares are unavailable for Japan, but cycles can be observed in employment and utilization. Figure 21 displays deviations from long-term trends in the

(e, u)-plane.

Japan's

cycles are mostly well-dened and clockwise oriented over most of the eight business cycles during the 1970-2008 sample period. The only exception is the last 2004q2-2008q2 peakto-peak business cycle, where no

(e, u)-cycle

seems apparent. Interestingly, while Japan

19 Business cycle turning points for OECD countries can be http://www.oecd.org/document/29/0,3343,en_2649_34349_35725597_1_1_1_1,00.html

11

found

at

is widely recognized to have suered a liquidity-trap or at least a slump since the 1990s, sucient volatility in the economy exists to generate

(e, u)

20

cycles.

Figure 21 - Deviation of employment and utilization in Japan from their long term trends in the

5

(e, u)-plane

Conclusion

The US economy since the second world war may provide the best arena for an evaluation of dierent approaches within heterodox macro.

The US is as close as one gets to a

closed economy, the size of the public sector is relatively modest, and unlike Japan and many European economies, the US did not have large amounts of hidden unemployment in backward sectors for a good part of the post-war period. With respect to data, moreover, quarterly series are available for some of the key variables in heterodox models. This paper describes stylized patterns in the data on employment, protability, capacity utilization and accumulation. The patterns are quite clear and consistent in the case of the US economy, and many of them exist for other OECD countries too, but are generally not as clean and consistent. For the US we nd that



the US employment rate, the prot share and the utilization rate uctuate around a mean of about 0.94, 0.81 and 0.28, respectively



the long-term trends of the variables  as measured by Hodrick-Prescott lter  exhibit modest variation.

The percentage point dierence between maximum and

minimum values of the HP trend is 2.7, 4.4.

and 5.7 for employment, the prot

share and the utilization rate, respectively. In proportional terms, the variation is largest for the prot share (15.6 percent) followed by utilization (7.0 percent ) and employment (2.8 percent).



short-term uctuations are signicant for all the variables but the amplitudes dier: typically less the 6 percentage points over a cycle for employment and the prot share and up to 15-20 percentage points for utilization. In proportional terms, the amplitude is similar for utilization and the prot share but much smaller for employment.



there is strong evidence of clockwise short-term cycles in three bivariate spaces:

(e, u), •

and

(e, π),

(u, π) (e, Yˆ ), (π, Yˆ ) and (u, Yˆ ) too, ˆ ˆ and (u, K) ˆ spaces are less (e, K), (π, K)

clockwise short-run cycles exist for

while the orienta-

tions of the cycles in the

consistent.

20

For dierent views on the reasons behind Japan's liquidity trap, see Krugman (1998) and Nakatani and Skott (2007). 12



the short-term cycles are synchronized with the standard NBER dating of business cycles



the cyclical patterns appear to be quite robust to changes in the precise denition and measurement of the variables.

The empirical analysis needs to go much further than a simple analysis of stylized patterns. But the presence of strong and consistent patterns can provide an input into the development and evaluation of economic theories. It is beyond the scope of this paper to discuss these issues. In a companion paper, Skott and Zipperer (2010a), we take a step in this direction by looking at the consistency of three post Keynesian benchmark models with the empirical evidence.

References [1] Barbosa-Filho, N.H., Taylor,L. (2006): Distributive and Demand Cycles in the US Economy - A Structuralist Goodwin Model, in

Metroeconomica

[2] Corrado, C., Mattey, J. (1997): Capacity utilization, in

tives, 11(1), 151-167.

Journal of Economic Perspec-

[3] Goodwin, R.M. (1967): A growth cycle, in C.H. Feinstein (ed.)

and growth, Cambridge:

57(3), 389-411.

Socialism, capitalism

Cambridge University Press.

[4] Harvie, D. (2000): Testing Goodwin: growth cycles in ten OECD countries, in

bridge Journal of Economics, 24(3), 349-376.

Cam-

[5] Hodrick, R.J., Prescott, E.C. (1997): Postwar U.S. Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation, in

Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 29(1), 1-16.

[6] Krugman, P. (1998): It's Baaack: Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap, in

Brooking's Papers on Economic Activity, 29(2), 137-205.

[7] Krueger, A.B. (1999): Measuring labor's share, in

and Proceedings, 89(2), 45-51.

American Economic Review, Papers

[8] Mohun, S., Veneziani, R. (2008): Goodwin cycles and the US economy, 1948- 2004, in

Mathematical Economics and the Dynamics of Capitalism - Goodwin's Legacy Continued, Routledge.

P. Flaschel and M. Landesmann (eds.),

[9] Mohun, S., Veneziani, R. (2009): Social democracy and class compromise, mimeo. [10] Nakatani, T., Skott, P. (2007): Japanese growth and stagnation, in

and Economic Dynamics, 18(3), 306-332.

13

Structural Change

[11] Ravn, M. O. and Uhlig, H. (2002): On adjusting the Hodrick-Prescott lter for the frequency of observations, in

Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), 371-375.

[12] Schmitt, J., Baker, D. (2006): Missing inaction: evidence of undercounting of nonworkers in the Current Population Survey,

Brieng Paper.

[13] Shapiro, M.D. (1989): Utilization, in

Center for Economic and Policy Research

Assessing the Federal Reserve's Measures of Capacity and

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1989, 181-225.

[14] Skott, P. (1989):

Conict and Eective Demand in Economic Growth.

Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press. [15] Skott (2010) "Theoretical and empirical shortcomings of the Kaleckian investment function" [16] Skott, P., Zipperer, B. (2010): Dynamic patterns of accumulation and income distribution, Political Economy Quarterly (Kikan Keizai Riron), 46 (4), pp.34-53 (in Japanese) [17] Skott, P., Zipperer, B. (2010a) "An empirical evaluation of three post Keynesian models". Working paper 2010-xx, University of Massachusetts Amherst.

14

Figures for Cyclical Patterns paper February 27, 2010

1

.1

.15

.2

.25

.3

.35

FIGURE 1 - US quarterly prot shares π and π 0 ; actual, and short-term and long-term trends

1950q1

1960q1

1970q1

1980q1 pi st_pi lt_pi

2

1990q1 pi’ st_pi’ lt_pi’

2000q1

2010q1

.7

.75

.8

.85

.9

FIGURE 2 - US quarterly manufacturing utilization rate u; actual, and short-term and long-term trends

1950q1

1960q1

1970q1

1980q1 u lt_u

3

1990q1 st_u

2000q1

2010q1

0

.005

.01

.015

.02

ˆ ; actual, and short-term and long-term trends FIGURE 3 - Quarterly Fed-based K

1950q1

1960q1

1970q1

1980q1

fed_khat lt_fed_khat

4

1990q1 st_fed_khat

2000q1

2010q1

−.02

0

.02

.04

.06

.08

ˆ ; actual and long-term trend FIGURE 4 - Annual Fed-based and BEA-based K

1940

1960

1980

fed_khat lt_fed_khat_descrip

5

2000 bea_khat lt_bea_khat_descrip

2020

.9

.92

.94

.96

.98

FIGURE 5 - US quarterly employment rate e; actual, and short-term and long-term trends

1950q1

1960q1

1970q1

1980q1 e lt_e

6

1990q1 st_e

2000q1

2010q1

−.04

−.02

0

.02

.04

FIGURE 6 - Dierence between the US mean and long-run trend, for utilization, employment, prot shares, and quarterly accumulation rate

1950q1

1960q1

1970q1

1980q1

u_deviation e_deviation

1990q1 pi_deviation khat_deviation

7

2000q1

2010q1

.35

FIGURE 7 - US actual and smoothed (e, π)-plane cycles

.33

1951 19651949 1955

1950

.31

1964

1966 1948

1952

.27

.29

2006

1983

1953

.23

.25

1982

1963 1962 1956 1967 1959 1960 2007 19571968 2005 1969 1997 1996 2008 1954 1984 1976 1985 1961 1972 1995 1973 1998 1971 2004 1999 1989 1988 1986 19941958 1991 1977 1990 1992 1978 2003 1970 2000 1987 1979 1993 1975 1974 1981 2002 2001 1980

.91

.93

.95

.97

.35

.89

.33

1951

.29

.31

1950

1984 1976

1985

.27

19771986 1992 1993 1975

1983

.25

1982

19491965 1966 1948 1952 1964 1955 1956 2006 1963 1967 2007 1953 1968 1962 1959 1960 1957 2005 1997 1969 2008 1961 1954 1996 1998 19581995 1972 1973 1999 1978 1971 1994 2004 1988 1989 1970 1990 1991 1987 2000 1979 2003 1974

1981

2002

2001

.23

1980

.89

.91

.93

8

.95

.97

.04 .02

.02

.04

Figure 8 - Deviation of US employment and prot shares from their long term trends in the (e, π)-plane.

1951

1955

−.02

1952 1953

0

0

1949

1956 1957

−.02

1950

1954

1954

−.04

−.04

1958

0

.02

.04

−.04

−.02

0

.02

.04

1965

.02

.02

.04

−.02

.04

−.04

1964 1968 1967 1969

0

0

1963 1962

−.02

19591960

−.02

1966

1961

1961 1970

−.04

−.04

1958

0

.02

.04

−.04

−.02

0

.02

.04

.02

.02

.04

−.02

.04

−.04

1976

0

−.04

1974 1970

−.04

−.02

0

.02

1977

.04

9

1978 1979

1975

−.02

−.02

1972 1971

1974 1980

−.04

0

1973

−.04

−.02

0

.02

.04

1989 1988

1986 1991

.04 .02 0

.04 .02 0

1984 1985

1987

1983

1990

1981 1982

−.02

−.02

1982

−.04

−.04

1980

0

.02

.04

−.04

−.02

0

.02

.04

2006

.02

.02

.04

−.02

.04

−.04

1997 1996

2005 2007

1993

−.02

0

2000

2004 2008 2003

−.02

0

1995 1998 1994 1999 1991 1992

2002

−.04

2001

−.04

2001

−.04

−.02

0

.02

.04

−.04

10

−.02

0

.02

.04

.1

.1

Figure 9 - Deviation of US employment and utilization from their long term trends in the (e, u)-plane.

.05

1953

.05

1951

1956 1957

1952

0

0

1955

1954

−.05

−.05

1954 1949 1950

−.1

−.1

1958

0

.05

.1

−.1

−.05

0

.05

.1

.05

.1

.05

.1

.1

−.05

.1

−.1

.05

.05

1966 1965 1967 1969 1968 1964

0

0

1960 1959

−.05

−.05

1963 1970 1962

0

.05

.1

1961

−.1

−.05

0

.05

.05

.1

−.05

.1

−.1

−.1

−.1

1958 1961

1973 1974

1979 1974

0

0

1980 1978 1977

−.05

−.05

1972 1970

1971

1976

−.1

−.05

0

.05

.1

11

−.1

−.1

1975

−.1

−.05

0

.1

.1

.05

.05

1989 1988 1990

0

0

1980

1987 1984 1985 1986 1991

−.05

−.05

1981

1982

1982

−.1

−.1

1983

0

.05

.1

−.1

−.05

0

.05

.1

.05

.1

.05

.05

.1

−.05

.1

−.1

2006 2007 2008 2005

0

0

1995 1998 1997 2000 1996 19941999 1993 1992 2001 1991

−.05

2002

−.1

−.1

−.05

20042001 2003

−.1

−.05

0

.05

.1

−.1

12

−.05

0

.1 .05

.05

.1

Figure 10 - Deviation of US utilization and prot shares from their long term trends in the (u, π)-plane.

1951 1952

1955

0

0

19501949

1953

1956 1957 1954

−.05

1958

−.1

−.1

−.05

1954

.1

−.1

.1

.05

.05

0

.1

−.05

.05

−.1

−.05

0

.05

1965 1966

1960

1961

1961

1968 1967 1969

1970

−.1

−.1

−.05

1958

−.05

1963 1962

0

0

1964 1959

.1

0

1971

1972

.05

.1

−.1

−.05

0

.05

.1

.05

1977 1978 1975

1979

1980 1974

−.1

−.05

0

.05

.1

13

−.1

−.1

−.05

1974

−.05

1970

1976

1973

0

0

.05

.1

−.05

.1

−.1

−.1

−.05

0

.05

.1

.1 .05 0

.1 .05 0

1983

1981

1982

−.1

−.1

−.05

1980

−.05

1982

1984 1985 1986 19881989 1991 1987 1990

0

.05

.1

−.1

−.05

0

.05

.1

.05

.05

.1

−.05

.1

−.1

0

0

1997 1996 1995 1998 1994 1999 1991 1992 1993 2000

2006 2005 2007 2008

2004 2003 2002

−.05

2001

−.1

−.1

−.05

2001

−.1

−.05

0

.05

.1

−.1

14

−.05

0

.05

.1

.04

Figure 11 - Smoothed cycles in the (e, Yˆ )-, (π, Yˆ )-, and (u, Yˆ )-planes.

1950 1955

1983

1977

1976 1993 1985 1992 1981 1986 1975

0

.02

1959 1984

1982

1965 1972 1962 1964 1978 1968 1997 1963 1987 199819991966 1994 1961 1951 1996 1973 2004 1971 1952 1988 1995 2005 2006 2003 1967 1969 1953 2000 1956 1954 1960 2002 1989 1979 1990 1991 1958 1980 2007 1949 1970 2008 1974

−.02

1957 2001

.92

.94

.96

.98

.04

.9

1950

1951

−.02

0

.02

1955 1959 1984 1965 1977 1972 1962 1983 1964 1978 1968 1963 1976 1997 1987 1998 1994 1966 1999 19612005 1996 2004 1971 1952 1988 1973 1985 1993 1995 1992 2003 19672006 2000 1956 1981 1953 1969 1986 1954 1960 1975 2002 1989 1958 19791991 1990 1980 2007 1949 1970 1982 2008 1957 2001 1974

.26

.28

.04

.24

.3

.32

.34

1950

.02

1959

1955

1984

1983

0

2003 2002

1965 1968 1951 1973 1956 1969

1966 1967 1953

1974

−.02

1982

1972 1977 1962 1964 1976 1997 1978 1963 1987 1998 199919941996 1961 2004 2005 1971 1952 1988 1993 1995 1985 1992 2006 2000 1981 1986 1954 1960 1975 1989 1958 1979 1991 1980 1990 2007 1949 1970 2008 1957 2001

.7

.75

.8

15

.85

.9

.005 .01 .015 .02

ˆ -, (π, K) ˆ -, and (u, K) ˆ -planes. Figure 12 - Smoothed cycles in the (e, K) 1998 1997 1996

1982

1976 1984

1981 1985 1977 1975 1992 1993 1986

1965

1967

1968 2000 1949 1956 1969 1995 1952 19571951 1953 1960 1950 1964 1955 1970 2001 1973 1961 1978 1954 1974 1963 1958 1959 1979 1971 1962 1972 1994 1980 1990 1987 1991 2007 1989 2008 1988 2006 2002 2005

0

1983

1966 1999

2004 2003

.005 .01 .015 .02

.9

.92

.94

.96

.98

1998 1997 1999

1996

0

1995 1970 2001 1973 1978 1974 1958 1979 1971 1972 1981 1985 1977 1994 1980 1990 1975 1982 1976 1987 1992 1993 1991 19861989 1984 1988 2002 1983

1949 1956 1969 1952 1957 1960 1953 1955 1964 1961 1954 19591962 1963

1950

1951

2007

2008

2006

2005

2004

2003

.005 .01 .015 .02

1965

1968

2000

.24

1966 1967

.26

.28

.3

.32

.34

1998 1997 1999

1995 1952 1957 1960 1970 1955 1964 1950 2001 1961 19541978 1963 1958 1979 1971 19851959 1981 1962 1972 1977 19801994 1990 19761975 1987 1992 1993 2007 1986 1991 1989 2008 1984 1988 2006 2005

1982

0

1983 2002

.7

1996

2000

1949

2003

1966 1967 1965 1968 1956 1969 1951 1973 1974

1953

2004

.75

.8

16

.85

.9

.34

FIGURE 13 - Smoothed cycles in Fed-based (u, π)- and output-based (u0 , π)-planes.

1951

.32

1950 1949

.3

2006 2007 1962 1959 1960

2005 2008 1961

.28

1958 1984 1976 2004

.26

1968 1997 1954 1996 1998 1995

1985

1957

1972 19991994 1989 1978 1977 19701988 1990 1991 1987 1992 1993 2000 1979

2003

1966

1956

1963

1967 1953

1969

1973

1971 1986

1975 1983

1965

1948 1952 1964 1955

1974

1982 1981

2002

2001

.24

1980

.75

.8

.85

.9

.34

.7

1951

.32

1950 1965 1949 1964

1966 1952

1955

1963 2007

.3

1962 1959

1960

1995

.28

1958

1976 1994

.26

19921975 1993 1983

2006 1956 1967 1968 1953

1957 2005 2008 1997 1954 1996

1961

1984 2004 1971 1977

1991

1948

1969

1998 1985 1972 1970 1986 1990 1987

2003

19991973 1989 1978 1988

1979

1974

2000

1982 1981 2002

2001

.24

1980

.9

.95

17

1

1.05

1.1

.8

.85

.9

.95

1

FIGURE 14 - Quarterly e, π , u for OECD countries

1970q1

1980q1

1990q1

2000q1

2010q1

1970q1

1980q1

1990q1

2000q1

2010q1

1970q1

1980q1

1990q1

2000q1

2010q1

.2

.3

.4

.5

1960q1

.6

.7

.8

.9

1

1960q1

1960q1

18

.03

.04

FIGURE 15 - Deviation of utilization and prot shares in France from their long term trends in the (u, π)-plane

1989

1990

.02

.02

1990

.01

1988

1987

1992 1991

0

1995

0

1986

−.02

1984

−.01

1994 1985

.02

.04

−.06 −.04 −.02

.02

.04

1998

2001

.005

1995

2000

0

.005

0

.01

0

.01

−.02

1993

0

1999

−.005

−.01 −.005

1996

1997

−.02

−.01

0

.01

.02

.01

−.03

.005

2001 20072008

−.005

0

2006

2003 2002

−.01

2004 2005

−.04

−.02

0

.02

.04

19

1999

−.01

0

.01

.02

.03

.04

.03

.04

FIGURE 16 - Deviation of employment and prot shares in France from their long term trends in the (e, π)-plane

1989

1990

.02

.02

1990

.01

1988

1987

1992 1991

0

1995

1984 1994

1993

−.01

−.02

0

1986

1985

.005

.01

.015

−.02

−.01

0

.01

.02

.01

0

.01

−.01 −.005

2001

1995

.005

.005

1998

0

2000

0

1999

1997

.01

−.014 −.012 −.01 −.008 −.006 −.004

2008

2007

2006

−.005

0

.005

2001

2003 2002

2004

−.01

2005

−.005

0

.005

.01

.01520

−.005

−.01 −.005

1996

1999

−.01 −.005

0

.005

.01

.015

Figure 17 - Deviation of employment and utilization in France from their long term trends in the (e, u)-plane

1986

−.02

1987 1984 1985

0

.005

.01

.04

.015

1993 1994

−.02

−.01

0

.01

.04

.02

−.01 −.005

1992

1995

−.06 −.04 −.02

0

1988

.02

2001

.02

.03

.01

1999

0

1995

2000 1999

0

.01

1996

−.01

−.03 −.02 −.01

1991

0

.02

1989

1998

1997

.04

−.014 −.012 −.01 −.008 −.006 −.004

.02

2001

2008 2007

2002

0

2003 2005

2004

2006

−.04

−.02

1990

.02

.04

1990

−.005

0

.005

.01

.01521

−.01 −.005

0

.005

.01

.015

.03

.02

FIGURE 18 - Deviation of utilization and prot shares in Spain from their long term trends in the (u, π)-plane

1986

1984

0

1987

.01

.01

.02

1988 1989

1985 1984

0

1980

1990

−.02 −.01

−.01

1983

−.02

1982

1981

.01

.02

.03

−.02

0

.02

.04

.01

0

.02

−.01

−.01

0

0

.01

1995

1991

1992

1994

1992

−.02

−.03 −.02 −.01

1990

−.03

1993

−.02

0

.02

.04

−.06

−.04

−.02

0

.02

.005

.01

−.04

.005

19971996

2004 2002

1995

2003

0

1998

1999

−.02

−.01

0

.01

.02

.03 22

−.005

−.005

0

2001

2000 1999

−.02

0

.02

.04

.03

.02

FIGURE 19 - Deviation of employment and prot shares in Spain from their long term trends in the (e, π)-plane

0

1984

1988 1987

.01

.01

.02

1986

1989

1985

1980

0

1984

−.02 −.01

−.01 −.02

1982

1981

.02

.04

−.04

−.02

0

.02

.04

.01

0

.02

−.02

−.01

−.03 −.02 −.01

1990

1991

1992

1994

1992

−.02

0

0

.01

1995

−.03

1993

.015

.02

.025

.03

.035

−.04

−.02

0

.02

.005

.01

.01

1996

.005

1990

1983

1997

2004 2002

1995 2003

0

1998

1999

−.03

−.02

−.01

0

.01 23

−.005

−.005

0

2001

1999

−.01

0

.01

2000

.02

.03

.04

.03

Figure 20 - Deviation of employment and utilization in Spain from their long term trends in the (e, u)-plane

1990

.01

.02

.02

1989

1987 1988

0

1982

1981

0

1983

1980

1985

1984

1984

−.02

−.01

1986

.02

.04

−.04

−.02

0

.02

.04

0

1990

1992

1992 1994

1993

−.04

−.06

−.02

1995

−.04

0

1991

−.02

.02

.02

0

.04

−.02

.02

.025

.03

.035

−.04

−.02

0

.02

.04

.015

.03

.01

.02

1999

.01

.02

1999

2001

0

0

1998

2003

−.02

1995

−.02 −.01

2000

1996 1997

−.03

−.02

−.01

0

.01 24

2004 2002

−.01

0

.01

.02

.03

.05

Figure 21 - Deviation of employment and utilization in Japan from their long term trends in the (e, u)-plane .06

1973

0

.02

−.05

.04

1974

1974

1976

−.1

1971

0

1977

−.15

−.02

1972

.002

.003

.004

.005

1980

−.004

−.002

0

.002

.05

.001

.05

0

1975

.004

1980

1985 1984

0

0

1979

−.05

1981 1978

1982

1977

−.1

−.05

1983

0

.001 .002

.1

−.003 −.002 −.001

1991 1990

.05

1989

1988 1985

0

1986

−.05

1987

−.005

0

.005

.01 25

−.004

−.002

0

.002

.05

.1 .05

1991

0

1997 1992

2000

0

1998 2001

−.05

1995

1998 1996

−.05

1993

1999

−.1

−.1

1994

.002

.004

.006

.008

−.01

−.005

0

.05

.05

0

.005

2008 2007 2006

2005 2005

0

0

2004

2001

−.05

−.05

2003

−.1

−.1

2002

−.015

−.01

−.005

0

−.005

26

0

.005

.01