(NMS)? - IMF

Report 10 Downloads 157 Views
EU funds: What can the Western Balkans learn from the New Member States (NMS)? Robert Sierhej, International Monetary Fund Regional Office in Warsaw October, 2007

Outline: „

An overview of available funds



Comparing IPA and pre-accession in the NMS Prospects for after-accession

„

Lessons from the NMS





Institutional and legal frameworks Challenges in economic policy

„

Conclusions



IPA commitments for Western Balkans Instrument for pre-accession assistance (IPA) (EU commitments, millions of Euro) 2007

2008

2009

2007-2009

138.5

146

151.2

436

Macedonia, FYR

59

70

82

211

Albania

61

71

81

213

Bosnia & Herzegovina

62

75

89

226

Montenegro

31

33

33

97

Serbia

187

191

195

572

Kosovo

63

65

66

194

463

504

546

1513

Croatia

Total

Source: European Commission (EC).

While IPA is lower than preaccession in the NMS… IPA and pre-accession commitments (annual average per country, Euro million) 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 WB

Source: EC, staff estimates

NMS10

…its economic significance is broadly comparable IPA and pre accession assistance in NMS (commitments in percent of GDP) 2.5

2.0

1.5 Weighted average 1.0

0.5

0.0 Croatia

Serbia

Source: EC, IMF, staff estimates

Bosnia and Herzegovina

Albania

Macedonia

Montenegro

Kosovo

NMS 10

And this may be just the beginning Comparison of pre-accession and post-accession funds in NMS (in percent of GDP) 4

3

2

1

0 Pre-accession Source: EC, Eurostat, staff estimates

2004-06

2007-13

How to manage the increasing EU funds? „

NMS developed two models: • “Baltic model”: single institution (MoF) acting as both managing and paying authority • “CE5 model”: different managing and payment authorities—MoF detached from managing role • Different role of regional authorities: the strongest in Poland, the largest country among NMS

It is hard to judge which model works better NMS: Absorption of EU structural funds (claims for interim EU refunds as of June 2007, in percent of 2004-06 commitments) 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% SI

HU

EE

Source: National authorities, EC, staff estimates

LT

SK

PL

LV

CZ

Poland’s case shows that complex initial setups may evolve… Poland: Initial Managing Authorities for EU-financed Operating Programs 1. Ministry of Economy

2. Ministry of Agriculture Industry

Fishery

Human Resource Development Cohesion funds (coordinating) 3. Ministry of Infrastructure

Rural Development 4. Ministry of Environment

Transport Cohesion funds (transport)

5. Local governments

Regional development

Cohesion funds (environment)

…to streamlined versions to ensure more efficient coordination Poland: Modified Managing Authorities for EU-financed Programs 1. Ministry of Regional Development

2. Ministry of Agriculture Industry

Human Resource Development

Fishery

Cohesion funds Transport 3. Local governments

Regional development

Rural Development

Poland: Legal and regulatory changes followed a similar route Poland: Measures to improve absorption of EU funds: Payment system

* more frequent and simplified submission of refund claims * accelerated certification of payments * simplified (one-stage) verification of invoices

Legal framework

* simplified public procurement rules * no court appeals on bids below Euro 60,000 * no ministerial regulations required in all program documents

"Political" suasion

* government monthly monitoring of absorption progress against planned targets

EU funds may be a challenge for fiscal policy

A simple framework for assessing the fiscal impact of EU transfers. (1) EU related receipts budget compensation refunds on EU projects (2) EU related expenditures contribution to EU spending on EU projects national co-financing Direct fiscal impact=(1)-(2) (3) Domestic spending substituted by EU transfers Adjusted fiscal impact (1)-(2)+(3)

Hungary: Fiscal impact of EU transfers (in percent of GDP) 2004

2005

2006

2007 budget

Transfers from EU

0.8

0.9

1.3

1.9

Expenditure on EU projects

0.4

0.9

1.3

1.8

Co-financing

0.2

0.4

0.7

0.7

Contribution to EU

0.6

0.8

0.8

0.8

Direct fiscal impact

-0.4

-1.3

-1.5

-1.3

Substituted spending 1/

0.2

0.7

1.1

1.5

Adjusted fiscal impact

-0.2

-0.6

-0.4

0.2

1/ Estimate: includes cohesion funds, CAP transfers, and co-financing.

Source:MoF, staff estimates

Demand impact: A very simplified approach D = α ( T + NC) - C – A ; α € {0,1} D - demand impact T - transfers received from EU NC - national co-financing of EU funds C - contributions paid to EU A - advances received α - degree of substitution between EU- related projects and domestic spending that would have happened anyway (depending on the implementation of additionality guidelines)

First round effect on demand depends on additionality assumptions Partial additionality (α= 0.55-0.65)

Full additionality (α=1) 4.5

4.5 4.0

4.0

2004-06 avg 2007-13 avg

3.5

3.5

3.0

3.0

2.5

2.5

2.0

2.0

1.5

1.5

1.0

1.0

0.5

0.5

0.0

0.0

-0.5

LT

EE

PL

SK

HU

LV

CZ

SI

Source: National authorities, staff estimates.

BG

RO

-0.5

2004-06 avg

2007-13 avg

LT HU PL EE SK LV CZ SI BG RO

Model-based estimates point at positive, albeit ambiguous, impact on growth Poland: Impact of cohesion policy on GDP level (deviation from baseline in %) 12 I m p le m e n t a t io n a l P h a s e (2 0 0 6 -2 0 1 5 )

T e r m in a t io n P h a s e (2 0 1 6 -2 0 2 0 )

10 EC O MO D

8

6

QU EST

4

H E R M IN

2

0 2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

Source: J. Bradley, G. Untiedt, “Do economic models tell us anything useful about Cohesion Policy impacts?, 2007

EU transfers could also have negative side-effects „

¾ ¾

If the recipient economy operates at its potential, the impulse from EU transfers could add to economic imbalances by: Creating pressure on wages and prices Leading to appreciation of the real effective exchange and undermining external competitiveness

Some conclusions based on the NMS’ experience: „

9

9

9

IPA may be just a prelude to much larger funding, it is important to use it well: Institutional and regulatory frameworks should ensure efficient coordination and relatively high degree of flexibility. A possible negative budgetary impact should be considered and, if necessary, prevented by reprioritizing expenditures. The demand impulse from EU transfers needs to be managed carefully not to add macroeconomic imbalances