Superhedging and Dynamic Risk Measures under ... - Columbia Math

Report 3 Downloads 38 Views
Superhedging and Dynamic Risk Measures under Volatility Uncertainty Marcel Nutz

βˆ—

†

H. Mete Soner

First version: November 12, 2010. This version: June 2, 2012.

Abstract We consider dynamic sublinear expectations (i.e., time-consistent coherent risk measures) whose scenario sets consist of singular measures corresponding to a general form of volatility uncertainty. We derive a cΓ dlΓ g nonlinear martingale which is also the value process of a superhedging problem. The superhedging strategy is obtained from a representation similar to the optional decomposition. Furthermore, we prove an optional sampling theorem for the nonlinear martingale and characterize it as the solution of a second order backward SDE. The uniqueness of dynamic extensions of static sublinear expectations is also studied.

Keywords volatility uncertainty, risk measure, time consistency, nonlinear martin-

gale, superhedging, replication, second order BSDE, 𝐺-expectation AMS 2000 Subject Classications primary 91B30, 93E20, 60G44; secondary 60H30 JEL Classications D81, G11.

Acknowledgements

Research supported by the European Research Council

Grant 228053-FiRM, the Swiss National Science Foundation Grant PDFM2120424/1 and the ETH Foundation.

The authors thank two anonymous

referees for helpful comments.

1

Introduction

Coherent risk measures were introduced in [1] as a way to quantify the risk associated with a nancial position. Since then, coherent risk measures and sublinear expectations (which are the same up to the sign convention) have been studied by numerous authors; see [15, 29, 30] for extensive references. βˆ— †

Department of Mathematics, Columbia University,

[email protected]

Department

and

of

Mathematics,

ETH

Zurich,

[email protected]

1

Swiss

Finance

Institute,

Most of these works consider the case where scenarios are probability measures absolutely continuous with respect to a given reference probability (important early exceptions are [14, 26]). The present paper studies dynamic sublinear expectations and superhedging under volatility uncertainty, which is naturally related to singular measures.

The concept of volatility uncer-

tainty was introduced in nancial mathematics by [2, 11, 21] and has recently

𝐺-expectations

received considerable attention due to its relation to

[27, 28]

and second order backward stochastic dierential equations [6, 32], called 2BSDEs for brevity. Any (static) sublinear expectation

β„°0∘ ,

dened on the set of bounded

measurable functions on a measurable space

(Ξ©, β„±),

has a convex-dual rep-

resentation

β„°0∘ (𝑋) = sup 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋]

(1.1)

𝑃 βˆˆπ’«

𝒫

for a certain set

of measures which are

𝜎 -additive

certain continuity properties (cf. [15, Section 4]).

as soon as

β„°0∘

satises

𝒫

The elements of

can

be seen as possible scenarios in the presence of uncertainty and hence (1.1) corresponds to the worst-case expectation. In this paper, we take the canonical space of continuous paths and

𝒫

Ξ©

to be

to be a set of martingale laws

for the canonical process, corresponding to dierent scenarios of volatilities. For this case,

𝒫

is typically not dominated by a nite measure and (1.1)

was studied in [5, 10, 11] by capacity-theoretic methods. We remark that from the pricing point of view, the restriction to the martingale case entails no loss of generality in an arbitrage-free setting. An example with arbitrage was studied in [13]. While any set of martingale laws gives rise to a static sublinear expectation via (1.1), we are interested in

dynamic

sublinear expectations; i.e.,

conditional versions of (1.1) satisfying a time-consistency property. If dominated by a probability

π‘ƒβˆ— ,

𝒫

is

a natural extension of (1.1) is given by β€²

β„°π‘‘βˆ˜,π‘ƒβˆ— (𝑋) = ess supπ‘ƒβˆ— 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ] π‘ƒβˆ— -a.s., 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ,π‘ƒβˆ— )

where

𝒫(β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ , π‘ƒβˆ— ) = {𝑃 β€² ∈ 𝒫 : 𝑃 β€² = π‘ƒβˆ—

on

ltration generated by the canonical process.

β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ }

𝒫

(see [7]).

π”½βˆ˜ = {β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ }

is the

Such dynamic expectations

are well-studied; in particular, time consistency of by a stability property of

and

β„° ∘,π‘ƒβˆ—

can be characterized

In the non-dominated case, we can

similarly consider the family of random variables

{β„°π‘‘βˆ˜,𝑃 (𝑋), 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫}.

Since

a reference measure is lacking, it is not straightforward to construct a single random variable

β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋)

such that β€²

β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋) = β„°π‘‘βˆ˜,𝑃 (𝑋) := ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ] 𝑃 -a.s.

for all

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

(1.2)

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ,𝑃 )

This problem of aggregation has been solved in several examples. ticular, the

𝐺-expectations

and random

2

𝐺-expectations

In par-

[23] (recalled in

Section 2) correspond to special cases of (1.2).

The construction of

𝐺-

expectations is based on a PDE, which directly yields random variables dened for all

πœ” ∈ Ξ©.

The random

𝐺-expectations

are dened pathwise

using regular conditional probability distributions. A general study of aggregation problems is presented in [31]; see also [4]. However, the study of aggregation is not an object of the present paper.

In view of the diverse

approaches, we shall proceed axiomatically and start with a given aggregated family

{β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋), 𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ]}.

𝐺-expectations,

Having in mind the example of (random)

this family is assumed to be given in the raw ltration

π”½βˆ˜

and without any regularity in the time variable. The main goal of the present paper is to provide basic technology for the study of dynamic sublinear expectations under volatility uncertainty as

{β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋), 𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ]}, we construct a corresponding cΓ dlΓ g process β„°(𝑋), called the β„° -martingale associated with 𝑋 , in a suitably enlarged ltration 𝔽 (Proposition 4.5). We use this

stochastic processes.

Given the family

process to dene the sublinear expectation at stopping times and prove an

β„° -martingales (Theorem 4.10). Furthermore, β„°(𝑋) into an integral of the canonical process

optional sampling theorem for we obtain a decomposition of

and an increasing process (Proposition 4.11), similarly as in the classical op-

β„° -martingale yields the dynamic 𝑋 yields the superhedging price of the nancial claim 𝑋 and the integrand 𝑍 superhedging strategy. We also provide a connection between β„° -martingales 𝑋 and 2BSDEs by characterizing (β„°(𝑋), 𝑍 ) as the minimal solution of such a tional decomposition [19]. In particular, the

backward equation (Theorem 4.16). Our last result concerns the uniqueness of time-consistent extensions and gives conditions under which (1.2) is indeed the only possible extension of the static expectation (1.1). In particular, we introduce the notion of local strict monotonicity to deal with the singularity of the measures (Proposition 5.3). To obtain our results, we rely on methods from stochastic optimal control and the general theory of stochastic processes. Indeed, from the point of view of dynamic programming,

β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋)

is the value process of a control

problem dened over a set of measures, and time consistency corresponds to Bellman's principle. Taking the control representation (1.2) as our starting point allows us to consider the measures

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫

separately in many

arguments and therefore to apply standard arguments of the general theory. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows.

In Section 2 we

detail the setting and notation. Section 3 relates time consistency to a pasting property.

In Section 4 we construct the

β„° -martingale

and provide the

optional sampling theorem, the decomposition, and the characterization by a 2BSDE. Section 5 studies the uniqueness of time-consistent extensions.

3

2

Preliminaries

We x a constant

𝑇 >0

Ξ© = {πœ” ∈ 𝐢([0, 𝑇 ]; R𝑑 ) : πœ”0 = 0}

and let

be the

canonical space of continuous paths equipped with the uniform topology. We

𝐡 the canonical process 𝐡𝑑 (πœ”) = πœ”π‘‘ , by 𝑃0 the Wiener measure π”½βˆ˜ = {β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ }0≀𝑑≀𝑇 , β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ = 𝜎(𝐡𝑠 , 𝑠 ≀ 𝑑) the raw ltration generated

denote by and by by

𝐡.

As in [10, 23, 33, 32] we shall use the so-called strong formulation of

volatility uncertainty in this paper; i.e., we consider martingale laws induced by stochastic integrals of

𝐡

under

𝑃0 .

More precisely, we dene

𝒫𝑆

to be

the set of laws

𝑃 𝛼 := 𝑃0 ∘ (𝑋 𝛼 )βˆ’1 ,

𝑋𝑑𝛼 :=

where

(𝑃0∫) 𝑑

𝛼𝑠1/2 𝑑𝐡𝑠 ,

𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ]

(2.1)

0 and

𝛼

π”½βˆ˜ -progressively measurable processes with values 𝑑×𝑑 denotes the set βˆ£π›Όπ‘‘ ∣ 𝑑𝑑 < ∞ 𝑃0 -a.s. Here π•Š>0 𝑑 βŠ‚ ℝ

ranges over all

π•Š>0 𝑑 satisfying

βˆ«π‘‡ 0

in of

strictly positive denite matrices and the stochastic integral in (2.1) is the ItΓ΄ integral under

𝑃0 ,

constructed in

coincides with the set denoted by

π”½βˆ˜

𝒫𝑆

(cf. [36, p. 97]). We remark that

𝒫𝑆

in [31].

𝒫 βŠ† 𝒫𝑆 which represents 𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ], we dene 𝐿1𝒫 (β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ) to variables 𝑋 satisfying

The basic object in this paper is a nonempty set the possible scenarios for the volatility. For be the space of

β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ -measurable

random

βˆ₯𝑋βˆ₯𝐿1 := sup βˆ₯𝑋βˆ₯𝐿1 (𝑃 ) < ∞, 𝒫

𝑃 βˆˆπ’«

βˆ₯𝑋βˆ₯𝐿1 (𝑃 ) := 𝐸[βˆ£π‘‹βˆ£]. More precisely, we take equivalences classes with 𝒫 -quasi-sure equality so that 𝐿1𝒫 (β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ) becomes a Banach space. (Two functions are equal 𝒫 -quasi-surely, 𝒫 -q.s. for short, if they are equal up to a 𝒫 -polar set. A set is called 𝒫 -polar if it is a 𝑃 -nullset for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 .) 1 1 ∘ We also x a nonempty subset β„‹ of 𝐿𝒫 := 𝐿𝒫 (ℱ𝑇 ) whose elements play the role of nancial claims. We emphasize that in applications, β„‹ is typically 1 smaller than 𝐿𝒫 . The following is a motivating example for many of the where

respect to

considerations in this paper.

Example 2.1. 𝐺-expectation

(i) Given real numbers

(for dimension

𝑑 = 1)

0 ≀ π‘Ž ≀ π‘Ž < ∞,

corresponds to the choice

} 𝒫 = 𝑃 𝛼 ∈ 𝒫𝑆 : π‘Ž ≀ 𝛼 ≀ π‘Ž 𝑃0 Γ— 𝑑𝑑-a.e. , {

cf. [10, Section 3]. Here the symbol

𝐺(𝛾) := If

𝑋 = 𝑓 (𝐡𝑇 )

the associated

𝐺

(2.2)

refers to the function

1 sup π‘Žπ›Ύ. 2 π‘Žβ‰€π‘Žβ‰€π‘Ž 𝑓 , then β„°π‘‘βˆ˜,𝐺 (𝑋) is dened equation βˆ’βˆ‚π‘‘ 𝑒 βˆ’ 𝐺(𝑒π‘₯π‘₯ ) = 0 with

for a suciently regular function

via the solution of the nonlinear heat

4

π‘’βˆ£π‘‘=𝑇 = 𝑓 . In [27], the mapping β„°π‘‘βˆ˜,𝐺 is extended to random variables of the form 𝑋 = 𝑓 (𝐡𝑑1 , . . . , 𝐡𝑑𝑛 ) by a stepwise evaluation of the PDE and nally to the βˆ₯ β‹… βˆ₯𝐿1 -completion β„‹ of the set of all such 𝒫 random variables. For 𝑋 ∈ β„‹, the 𝐺-expectation then satises boundary condition

β€²

β„°π‘‘βˆ˜,𝐺 (𝑋) = ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ] 𝑃 -a.s.

for all

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫,

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ,𝑃 )

β„‹ coincides with the βˆ₯β‹…βˆ₯𝐿1 -completion 𝒫 𝐢𝑏 (Ξ©), the set of bounded continuous functions on Ξ©, and is strictly smaller 1 than 𝐿𝒫 as soon as π‘Ž βˆ•= π‘Ž. (ii) The random 𝐺-expectation corresponds to the case where π‘Ž, π‘Ž are

which is of the form (1.2). The space of

random processes instead of constants and is directly constructed from a set

𝒫

of measures (cf. [23]). In this case the space

of

UC𝑏 (Ξ©),

β„‹

βˆ₯ β‹… βˆ₯𝐿1 -completion 𝒫 functions on Ξ©. If π‘Ž is

is the

the set of bounded uniformly continuous

nite-valued and uniformly bounded,

3

β„‹

coincides with the space from (i).

Time Consistency and Pasting

𝒫 βŠ† 𝒫𝑆 β„‹ βŠ† 𝐿1𝒫 is xed π”½βˆ˜ -stopping times

In this section, we consider time consistency as a property of the set and obtain some auxiliary results for later use. throughout.

Moreover, we let

𝒯 (π”½βˆ˜ )

The set

be the set of all

taking nitely many values; this choice is motivated by the applications in the subsequent section. However, the results of this section hold true also if

𝒯 (π”½βˆ˜ )

is replaced by an arbitrary set of

π”½βˆ˜ -stopping

times containing

𝜎 ≑ 0;

in particular, the set of all stopping times and the set of all deterministic times. Given

π’œ βŠ† β„±π‘‡βˆ˜

and

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫,

we use the standard notation

𝒫(π’œ, 𝑃 ) = {𝑃 β€² ∈ 𝒫 : 𝑃 β€² = 𝑃

on

π’œ}.

At the level of measures, time consistency can then be dened as follows.

Denition 3.1. ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽβˆ˜ ,𝑃 )

β€²

[

The set

ess sup𝑃

𝒫 β€²

𝑃 β€²β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœβˆ˜ ,𝑃 β€² )

π”½βˆ˜ -time-consistent on β„‹ if ] β€²β€² β€² 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ] β„±πœŽβˆ˜ = ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽβˆ˜ ] 𝑃 -a.s. β€² ∘ is

𝑃 βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽ ,𝑃 )

(3.1) for all

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫, 𝑋 ∈ β„‹

and

πœŽβ‰€πœ

in

𝒯 (π”½βˆ˜ ).

This property embodies the principle of dynamic programming (e.g., [12]). We shall relate it to the following notion of stability, also called mstability, fork-convexity, stability under concatenation, etc.

Denition 3.2. 𝜏 βˆˆπ’―

(π”½βˆ˜ ),

𝒫 is stable under π”½βˆ˜ -pasting if for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 , Ξ›βˆˆ 𝑃1 , 𝑃2 ∈ 𝒫(β„±πœβˆ˜ , 𝑃 ), the measure 𝑃¯ dened by [ ] 𝑃¯ (𝐴) := 𝐸 𝑃 𝑃1 (π΄βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ )1Ξ› + 𝑃2 (π΄βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ )1Λ𝑐 , 𝐴 ∈ β„±π‘‡βˆ˜ (3.2) The set

β„±πœβˆ˜ and

is again an element of

𝒫. 5

As

π”½βˆ˜

is the only ltration considered in this section, we shall sometimes

∘

omit the qualier  𝔽 .

Lemma 3.3. The set 𝒫𝑆 is stable under pasting. Proof.

𝑃, 𝑃1 , 𝑃2 , 𝜏, Ξ›, 𝑃¯ be as in Denition 3.2. Using the notation (2.1), 𝑖 𝛼 𝛼𝑖 = 𝑃 for 𝑖 = 1, 2. Setting let 𝛼, 𝛼 be such that 𝑃 = 𝑃 and 𝑃 𝑖 Let

𝛼 Β― 𝑒 (πœ”) := [ ] 1[[0,𝜏 (𝑋 𝛼 )]] (𝑒)𝛼𝑒 (πœ”) + 1]]𝜏 (𝑋 𝛼 ),𝑇 ]] (𝑒) 𝛼𝑒1 (πœ”)1Ξ› (𝑋 𝛼 (πœ”)) + 𝛼𝑒2 (πœ”)1Λ𝑐 (𝑋 𝛼 (πœ”)) , we have

𝑃¯ = 𝑃 𝛼¯ ∈ 𝒫𝑆

by the arguments in [33, Appendix].

The previous proof also shows that the set appearing in (2.2) is stable under pasting. The following result is classical.

Lemma 3.4. Let 𝜏 ∈ 𝒯 (π”½βˆ˜ ), 𝑋 ∈ 𝐿1𝒫 and 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 . If 𝒫 is stable under pasting, then there exists a sequence 𝑃𝑛 ∈ 𝒫(β„±πœβˆ˜ , 𝑃 ) such that β€²

ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ] = lim 𝐸 𝑃𝑛 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ] π‘›β†’βˆž

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœβˆ˜ ,𝑃 )

𝑃 -a.s.,

where the limit is increasing 𝑃 -a.s. Proof.

a.s. upward ltering (cf. [22,

β€²

{𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ] : 𝑃 β€² ∈ 𝒫(β„±πœβˆ˜ , 𝑃 )} is 𝑃 ∘ Proposition VI-1-1]). Given 𝑃1 , 𝑃2 ∈ 𝒫(β„±πœ , 𝑃 ),

It suces to show that the family

we set

and dene and

𝑃¯ ∈ 𝒫

{ } Ξ› := 𝐸 𝑃1 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ] > 𝐸 𝑃2 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ] ∈ β„±πœβˆ˜ [ ] 𝑃¯ (𝐴) := 𝐸 𝑃 𝑃1 (π΄βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ )1Ξ› + 𝑃2 (π΄βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ )1Λ𝑐 . Then 𝑃¯ = 𝑃

on

β„±πœβˆ˜

by the stability. Moreover,

Β―

𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ] = 𝐸 𝑃1 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ] ∨ 𝐸 𝑃2 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ] 𝑃 -a.s., showing that the family is upward ltering. To relate time consistency to stability under pasting, we introduce the following closedness property.

Denition 3.5. 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫𝑆 If

𝒫

𝒫 is maximally chosen for β„‹ β€² 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋] ≀ sup𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’« 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋] for all 𝑋 ∈ β„‹.

We say that

satisfying

is dominated by a reference probability

with a subset of

𝐿1 (π‘ƒβˆ— )

π‘ƒβˆ— ,

then

𝒫

if

𝒫

contains all

can be identied

by the Radon-Nikodym theorem.

If furthermore

β„‹ = 𝐿∞ (π‘ƒβˆ— ), the Hahn-Banach theorem implies that 𝒫 is maximally chosen 1 if and only if 𝒫 is convex and closed for weak topology of 𝐿 (π‘ƒβˆ— ). Along these lines, the following result can be seen as a generalization of [7, Theorem 12]; in fact, we merely replace functional-analytic arguments by algebraic ones.

6

Proposition 3.6. With respect to the ltration π”½βˆ˜ , we have: (i) If 𝒫 is stable under pasting, then 𝒫 is time-consistent on 𝐿1𝒫 . (ii) If 𝒫 is time-consistent on β„‹ and maximally chosen for β„‹, then 𝒫 is stable under pasting. Proof. (i) This implication is standard; we provide the argument for later

𝑃 β€²β€² := 𝑃 β€² on arbitrary 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫

reference. The inequality  β‰₯ in (3.1) follows by considering the left hand side. To see the converse inequality, x an and choose a sequence

𝑃𝑛 ∈ 𝒫(β„±πœβˆ˜ , 𝑃 ) βŠ† 𝒫(β„±πœŽβˆ˜ , 𝑃 )

as in Lemma 3.4. Then

monotone convergence yields

𝐸

𝑃

[

𝑃

ess sup

𝐸

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœβˆ˜ ,𝑃 )

𝑃′



[π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ] β„±πœŽβˆ˜

]

= lim 𝐸 𝑃𝑛 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽβˆ˜ ] π‘›β†’βˆž

β€²

≀ ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽβˆ˜ ] 𝑃 -a.s. 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽβˆ˜ ,𝑃 )

𝒫

(ii) Let

be time-consistent and let

tion 3.2. For any

𝑋 ∈ β„‹,

𝑃, 𝑃1 , 𝑃2 , 𝜏, Ξ›, 𝑃¯

be as in Deni-

we have

[ ] Β― 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋] = 𝐸 𝑃 𝐸 𝑃1 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ]1Ξ› + 𝐸 𝑃2 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ]1Λ𝑐 [ ] 𝑃 𝑃 𝑃 β€²β€² ∘ ≀𝐸 ess sup 𝐸 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœ ] 𝑃 β€²β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœβˆ˜ ,𝑃 )

≀ sup 𝐸 𝑃

β€²

[

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«

ess sup𝑃

β€²

𝑃 β€²β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœβˆ˜ ,𝑃 β€² )

] β€²β€² 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜ ]

β€²

= sup 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋], 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’« where the last equality uses (3.1) with and

4

𝑃¯ ∈ 𝒫𝑆

𝜎 ≑ 0.

by Lemma 3.3, we conclude that

Since 𝒫 Β― 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

is maximally chosen

β„° -Martingales

As discussed in the introduction, our starting point in this section is a given

{β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋), 𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ]} of random variables which will serve as a raw version of the β„° -martingale to be constructed. We recall that the sets 𝒫 βŠ† 𝒫𝑆 1 and β„‹ βŠ† 𝐿𝒫 are xed. family

Assumption 4.1.

Throughout Section 4, we assume that

𝑋 ∈ β„‹ and 𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ], ∘ variable ℰ𝑑 (𝑋) such that

(i) for all

there exists an

β€²

β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋) = ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ] 𝑃 -a.s. 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ,𝑃 )

(ii) the set

𝒫

is stable under

π”½βˆ˜ -pasting.

7

β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ -measurable for all

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

random

(4.1)

The rst assumption was discussed in the introduction; cf. (1.2). With the motivating Example 2.1 in mind, we ask for (4.1) to hold at deterministic times rather than at stopping times. The second assumption is clearly motivated by Proposition 3.6(ii), and Proposition 3.6(i) shows that

𝒫

is

time-consistent in the sense of Denition 3.1. (We could assume the latter property directly, but stability under pasting is more suitable for applications.) In particular, we have β€²

β„°π‘ βˆ˜ (𝑋) = ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋)βˆ£β„±π‘ βˆ˜ ] 𝑃 -a.s.

for all

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫,

(4.2)

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±π‘ βˆ˜ ,𝑃 )

0 ≀ 𝑠 ≀ 𝑑 ≀ 𝑇 and 𝑋 ∈ β„‹. If we assume that β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋) is again an element ∘ of the domain β„‹, this amounts to {ℰ𝑑 } being time-consistent (at determin∘ ∘ ∘ istic times) in the sense that the semigroup property ℰ𝑠 ∘ ℰ𝑑 = ℰ𝑠 is satis∘ ed. However, ℰ𝑑 (𝑋) need not be in β„‹ in general; e.g., for certain random 𝐺-expectations. Inspired by the theory of viscosity solutions, we introduce the following extended notion of time consistency, which is clearly implied by (4.2).

Denition 4.2. A family (𝔼𝑑 )0≀𝑑≀𝑇 of mappings 𝔼𝑑 : β„‹ β†’ 𝐿1𝒫 (β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ) is called π”½βˆ˜ -time-consistent at deterministic times if for all 0 ≀ 𝑠 ≀ 𝑑 ≀ 𝑇 and 𝑋 ∈ β„‹, 𝔼𝑠 (𝑋) ≀ (β‰₯) 𝔼𝑠 (πœ‘)

for all

πœ‘ ∈ 𝐿1𝒫 (β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ) ∩ β„‹

such that

𝔼𝑑 (𝑋) ≀ (β‰₯) πœ‘.

One can give a similar denition for stopping times taking countably many values. (Note that stopping time

π”Όπœ (𝑋)

is not necessarily well dened for a general

𝜏 .)

Remark 4.3. If Assumption 4.1 is weakened by requiring 𝒫 to be stable only under

π”½βˆ˜ -pastings at deterministic times (i.e., Denition 3.1 holds with 𝒯 (π”½βˆ˜ )

replaced by the set of deterministic times), then all results in this section remain true with the same proofs, except for Theorem 4.10, Lemma 4.15 and the last statement in Theorem 4.16.

4.1

Construction of the

β„° -Martingale

Our rst task is to turn the collection

{β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋), 𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ]} of random variables

into a reasonable stochastic process. As usual, this requires an extension of the ltration. We denote by

𝔽+ = {ℱ𝑑+ }0≀𝑑≀𝑇 ,

∘ ℱ𝑑+ := ℱ𝑑+

the minimal right continuous ltration containing

∘ and ℱ𝑇 +

0≀𝑑𝑑 ℱ𝑠 𝒫 𝒩 of

∩

𝔽+ by the collection

to obtain the ltration

F = {ℱ𝑑 }0≀𝑑≀𝑇 ,

∘ := ℱ𝑑+

Then

F is right continuous and a natural analogue of the usual augmen-

tation that is standard in the case where a reference probability is given. More precisely, if

𝒫

is dominated by some probability measure, then one

can nd a minimal dominating measure a

π‘ƒβˆ— -nullset)

mark that

and then

π‘ƒβˆ—

(such that every

𝒫 -polar

F is in general strictly smaller than the 𝒫 -universal augmentation

βˆ˜π‘ƒ 𝑃 βˆˆπ’« 𝔽 , which seems to be too large for our purposes. Here ∘ the 𝑃 -augmentation of 𝔽 .

∩

Since

set is

F coincides with the π‘ƒβˆ— -augmentation of 𝔽+ . We re-

𝔽

and

F+

π”½βˆ˜

𝑃

denotes

𝒫 -polar sets, they can be identied for + ∘ that ℱ𝑇 = ℱ𝑇 = ℱ𝑇 𝒫 -q.s. We also recall

dier only by

most purposes; note in particular

the following result (e.g., [17, Theorem 1.5], [31, Lemma 8.2]), which shows that

F and π”½βˆ˜ dier only by 𝑃 -nullsets for each 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 .

Lemma 4.4. Let 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 . Then π”½βˆ˜ 𝑃 is right continuous and in particular contains F. Moreover, (𝑃, 𝐡) has the predictable representation property; i.e., for any right continuous (π”½βˆ˜ 𝑃 , 𝑃 )-local martingale 𝑀 there exists an ∫ 𝑃 π”½βˆ˜ -predictable process 𝑍 such that 𝑀 = 𝑀0 + (𝑃 ) 𝑍 𝑑𝐡 , 𝑃 -a.s. Proof.

We sketch the argument for the convenience of the reader. We dene

π‘Ž ˆ𝑑 = π‘‘βŸ¨π΅βŸ©π‘‘ /𝑑𝑑 taking values in π•Š>0 𝑑 𝑃 Γ— 𝑑𝑑-a.e., note βˆ’1/2 that (Λ† π‘Ž) ∫ is square-integrable for 𝐡 by its very denition, and consider 𝑑 π‘Žπ‘’ )βˆ’1/2 𝑑𝐡𝑒 . Let π”½π‘Š be the raw ltration generated by π‘Š . Since π‘Šπ‘‘ := (𝑃 ) 0 (Λ† a predictable process

π‘Š is a 𝑃 -Brownian motion by LΓ©vy's characterization, the 𝑃 -augmentation 𝑃 π”½π‘Š is right continuous and π‘Š has the representation property. Moreover, 𝑃 𝑃 𝑃 as 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫𝑆 , [31, Lemma 8.1] yields that π”½π‘Š = π”½βˆ˜ . Thus π”½βˆ˜ is also right continuous and 𝐡 has the representation property since any integral of π‘Š is also an integral of 𝐡 . We deduce from Lemma 4.4 that for is a (local) cess

𝐡.

𝒫 -polar

(F, 𝑃 )-martingale.

In particular, this applies to the canonical pro-

Note that Lemma 4.4 does not imply that

F and π”½βˆ˜ coincide up to

sets. E.g., consider the set

𝐴 :=

{

} ∘ lim sup π‘‘βˆ’1 βŸ¨π΅βŸ©π‘‘ = lim inf π‘‘βˆ’1 βŸ¨π΅βŸ©π‘‘ = 1 ∈ β„±0+ . 𝑑→0

𝑑→0

Then the lemma asserts that number is the same for all for

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 , any (local) (π”½βˆ˜ , 𝑃 )-martingale

𝑃.

(4.3)

𝑃 (𝐴) ∈ {0, 1} for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 , but not that this 𝛼 𝛼 Indeed, 𝑃 (𝐴) = 1 for 𝛼 ≑ 1 but 𝑃 (𝐴) = 0

𝛼 ≑ 2. We can now state the existence and uniqueness of the stochastic process

{β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋), 𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ]}. For brevity, we shall say that π‘Œ is an (F, 𝒫)-supermartingale if π‘Œ is an (F, 𝑃 )-supermartingale for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 ; derived from

analogous notation will be used in similar situations.

9

Proposition 4.5. Let 𝑋 ∈ β„‹. There exists an F-optional process (π‘Œπ‘‘ )0≀𝑑≀𝑇 such that all paths of π‘Œ are cΓ dlΓ g and (i) π‘Œ is the minimal (F, 𝒫)-supermartingale with π‘Œπ‘‡ = 𝑋 ; i.e., if 𝑆 is a cΓ dlΓ g (F, 𝒫)-supermartingale with 𝑆𝑇 = 𝑋 , then 𝑆 β‰₯ π‘Œ up to a 𝒫 -polar set. ∘ (𝑋) := lim ∘ (ii) π‘Œπ‘‘ = ℰ𝑑+ π‘Ÿβ†“π‘‘ β„°π‘Ÿ (𝑋) 𝒫 -q.s. for all 0 ≀ 𝑑 < 𝑇 , and π‘Œπ‘‡ = 𝑋 . (iii) π‘Œ has the representation 𝑃 -a.s.

β€²

π‘Œπ‘‘ = ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±π‘‘ ] 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(ℱ𝑑 ,𝑃 )

for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

(4.4)

Any of the properties (i),(ii),(iii) characterizes π‘Œ uniquely up to 𝒫 -polar sets. The process π‘Œ is denoted by β„°(𝑋) and called the (cΓ dlΓ g) β„° -martingale associated with 𝑋 . Proof.

We choose and x representatives for the classes

and dene the

π‘Œπ‘‘ (πœ”) :=

ℝ βˆͺ {±∞}-valued lim sup

process

β„°π‘Ÿβˆ˜ (𝑋)(πœ”)

for

π‘Œ

β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋) ∈ 𝐿1𝒫 (β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ )

by

0≀𝑑 𝑑, moreover, 𝒫(β„± ∘ , 𝑃 ) = 𝒫(β„± , 𝑃 ) since 𝒫(ℱ𝑑𝑛 , 𝑃 ) βŠ† 𝒫(ℱ𝑑+ 𝑛 𝑑 𝑑+ ∘ and β„± coincide up to 𝒫 -polar sets. In view of (4.6), the inequality ℱ𝑑+ 𝑑

since

converse to (4.5) follows and (iii) is proved. To see the minimality property in (i), let with

𝑆𝑇 = 𝑋 .

𝑆

be an

β€²

𝑆𝑑 β‰₯ ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±π‘‘ ] 𝑃 -a.s. 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±

for all

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

𝑑 ,𝑃 )

By (iii) the right hand side is all

(F, 𝒫)-supermartingale

Exactly as in (4.5), we deduce that

𝑃 -a.s.

equal to

π‘Œπ‘‘ .

Hence

𝑆𝑑 β‰₯ π‘Œπ‘‘ 𝒫 -q.s.

for

𝑆 β‰₯ π‘Œ 𝒫 -q.s. when 𝑆 is cΓ dlΓ g π‘Œ and π‘Œ β€² are processes satisfying (i) or (ii) or (iii), then they 𝑃 -modications of each other for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 and thus coincide up to a

𝑑

and

Finally, if are

𝒫 -polar

set as soon as they are cΓ dlΓ g.

One can ask whether

β„°(𝑋)

is a

𝒫 -modication

of

{β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋), 𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ]};

i.e., whether

ℰ𝑑 (𝑋) = β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋) 𝒫 -q.s.

for all

0 ≀ 𝑑 ≀ 𝑇.

β„°(𝑋) is a 𝒫 -modication as soon as there exists some 𝒫 -modication of the family {β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋), 𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ]}, and this is the case 𝑃 ∘ only if 𝑑 7β†’ 𝐸 [ℰ𝑑 (𝑋)] is right continuous for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 . We also

It is easy to see that cΓ dlΓ g if and

remark that Lemma 4.4 and the argument given for (4.5) yield

ℰ𝑑 (𝑋) ≀ β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋) 𝒫 -q.s.

for all

0≀𝑑≀𝑇

(4.7)

and so the question is only whether the converse inequality holds true as well. The answer is positive in several important cases; e.g., for the

11

𝐺-expectation

when

𝑋

is suciently regular [35, Theorem 5.3] and the sublinear expec-

tation generated by a controlled stochastic dierential equation [24, Theorem 5.1]. The proof of the latter result yields a general technique to approach this problem in a given example. However, the following (admittedly degenerate) example shows that the answer is negative in a very general case; this reects the fact that the set than the set

𝒫(β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ , 𝑃 )

𝒫(ℱ𝑑 , 𝑃 )

in the representation (4.4) is smaller

in (4.1).

Example 4.6. We shall consider a 𝐺-expectation dened on a set of irregular random variables.

∘ ) β„‹ = 𝐿1𝒫 (β„±0+

Let

π‘Ž = 1, π‘Ž = 2

and let

𝒫

be as in (2.2).

We take

and dene

{ sup𝑃 βˆˆπ’« 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋], 𝑑 = 0, β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋) := 𝑋, 0 0. As noted after Lemma 3.3, the second part of Assumption 4.1 is also satised. Moreover, the cΓ dlΓ g β„° -martingale is given by for

ℰ𝑑 (𝑋) = 𝑋,

𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ].

𝑋 := 1𝐴 , where 𝐴 is dened as in (4.3). Then β„°0∘ (𝑋) = 1 and β„°0 (𝑋) = 1𝐴 are not equal 𝑃 2 -a.s. (i.e., the measure 𝑃 𝛼 for 𝛼 ≑ 2). In fact, 2 ∘ there is no cΓ dlΓ g 𝒫 -modication since {ℰ𝑑 (𝑋)} coincides 𝑃 -a.s. with the deterministic function 𝑑 7β†’ 1{0} (𝑑).

Consider

We remark that the phenomenon appearing in the previous example is

𝒫

due to the presence of singular measures rather than the fact that

is

not dominated. In fact, one can give a similar example involving only two measures. Finally, let us mention that the situation is quite dierent if we assume that the given sublinear expectation is already placed in the larger ltration

𝔽

(i.e., Assumption 4.1 holds with

π”½βˆ˜

replaced by

𝔽),

which would be in line

with the paradigm of the usual assumptions in standard stochastic analysis. In this case, the arguments in the proof of Proposition 4.5 show that is always a

𝒫 -modication.

This result is neat, but not very useful, since the

examples are typically constructed in

4.2

β„°(𝑋)

π”½βˆ˜ .

Stopping Times

The direct construction of

𝐺-expectations

at stopping times is an unsolved

problem. Indeed, stopping times are typically fairly irregular functions and it is unclear how to deal with this in the existing constructions (see also [20]). On the other hand, we can easily evaluate the cΓ dlΓ g process stopping time tion at

𝜏.

𝜏

β„°(𝑋)

at a

and therefore dene the corresponding sublinear expecta-

In particular, this leads to a denition of

12

𝐺-expectations at general

stopping times. We show in this section that the resulting random variable

β„°πœ (𝑋)

indeed has the expected properties and that the time consistency ex-

tends to arbitrary

𝔽-stopping times; in other words, we prove an optional β„° -martingales. Besides the obvious theoretical interest,

sampling theorem for the study of

β„°(𝑋)

at stopping times will allow us to verify integrability con-

ditions of the type class (D); cf. Lemma 4.15 below. We start by explaining the relations between the stopping times of the dierent ltrations.

Lemma 4.7. (i) Let 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 and let 𝜏 be an F-stopping time taking countably many values. Then there exists an π”½βˆ˜ -stopping time 𝜏 ∘ (depending on 𝑃 ) such that 𝜏 = 𝜏 ∘ 𝑃 -a.s. Moreover, for any such 𝜏 ∘ , the 𝜎-elds β„±πœ and β„±πœβˆ˜βˆ˜ dier only by 𝑃 -nullsets. (ii) Let 𝜏 be an F-stopping time. Then there exists an 𝔽+ -stopping time + 𝜏 such that 𝜏 = 𝜏 + 𝒫 -q.s. Moreover, for any such 𝜏 + , the 𝜎 -elds β„±πœ and β„±πœ++ dier only by 𝒫 -polar sets. βˆ‘ Proof. (i) Note that 𝜏 is of the form 𝜏 = 𝑖 𝑑𝑖 1Λ𝑖 for Λ𝑖 = {𝜏 = 𝑑𝑖 } ∈ ℱ𝑑𝑖 forming a partition of such that

Ξ©.

Λ𝑖 = Ξ›βˆ˜π‘– 𝑃 -a.s.

Since

F βŠ† π”½βˆ˜ 𝑃 by Lemma 4.4, we can nd Ξ›βˆ˜π‘– ∈ β„±π‘‘βˆ˜

𝑖

and the rst assertion follows by taking

𝜏 ∘ := 𝑇 1(βˆͺ𝑖 Ξ›βˆ˜π‘– )𝑐 +

βˆ‘

𝑑𝑖 1Ξ›βˆ˜π‘– .

𝑖

𝐴 ∈ β„±πœ . By the rst part, there exists an π”½βˆ˜ -stopping time (𝜏𝐴 )∘ ∘ β€² ∘ that (𝜏𝐴 ) = 𝜏𝐴 := 𝜏 1𝐴 + 𝑇 1𝐴𝑐 𝑃 -a.s. Moreover, we choose 𝐴 ∈ ℱ𝑇 β€² that 𝐴 = 𝐴 𝑃 -a.s. Then ( ) 𝐴∘ := 𝐴′ ∩ {𝜏 ∘ = 𝑇 } βˆͺ {(𝜏𝐴 )∘ = 𝜏 ∘ < 𝑇 }

Let such such

𝐴∘ ∈ β„±πœβˆ˜βˆ˜ and 𝐴 = 𝐴∘ 𝑃 -a.s. A similar but simpler argument shows ∘ β€² β€² that for given Ξ› ∈ β„±πœ ∘ we can nd Ξ› ∈ β„±πœ such that Ξ› = Ξ› 𝑃 -a.s. + 𝑛 (ii) If 𝜏 is an F- (resp. 𝔽 -) stopping time, we can nd 𝜏 taking count𝑛 + ably many values such that 𝜏 decreases to 𝜏 and since F (𝔽 ) is right + + continuous, β„±πœ 𝑛 (β„±πœ 𝑛 ) decreases to β„±πœ (β„±πœ ). As a result, we may assume without loss of generality that 𝜏 takes countably many values. βˆ‘ Let 𝜏 = 𝑖 𝑑𝑖 1Λ𝑖 , where Λ𝑖 ∈ ℱ𝑑𝑖 . The denition of F shows that there + + + exist Λ𝑖 ∈ ℱ𝑑 such that Λ𝑖 = Λ𝑖 𝒫 -q.s. and the rst part follows. The proof 𝑖 satises

of the second part is as in (i); we now have quasi-sure instead of almost-sure relations.

𝜎 is a stopping taking nitely many values (𝑑𝑖 )1≀𝑖≀𝑁 , we can βˆ‘π‘ time ∘ ∘ dene β„°πœŽ (𝑋) := 𝑖=1 ℰ𝑑𝑖 (𝑋)1{𝜎=𝑑𝑖 } . We have the following generalization If

of (4.1).

Lemma 4.8. Let 𝜎 be an π”½βˆ˜ -stopping time taking nitely many values. Then β€²

β„°πœŽβˆ˜ (𝑋) = ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽβˆ˜ ] 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽβˆ˜ ,𝑃 )

13

𝑃 -a.s.

for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

Proof.

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 and π‘Œπ‘‘βˆ˜ := β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋). Moreover, let (𝑑𝑖 )1≀𝑖≀𝑁 be the values ∘ of 𝜎 and Λ𝑖 := {𝜎 = 𝑑𝑖 } ∈ ℱ𝑑 . 𝑖 β€² (i) We rst prove the inequality  β‰₯. Given 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 , it follows from (4.2) ∘ β€² ∘ that {π‘Œπ‘‘ }1≀𝑖≀𝑁 is a 𝑃 -supermartingale in (ℱ𝑑 )1≀𝑖≀𝑁 and so the (discrete𝑖 𝑖 ∘ 𝑃′ ∘ time) optional sampling theorem [9, Theorem V.11] implies π‘ŒπœŽ β‰₯ 𝐸 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] β€² β€² ∘ 𝑃 -a.s. In particular, this also holds 𝑃 -a.s. for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫(β„±πœŽ , 𝑃 ), hence the Let

claim follows. (ii) We now show the inequality  ≀. Note that

(Λ𝑖 )1≀𝑖≀𝑁

form an

β„±πœŽβˆ˜ -measurable

partition of

β€²

π‘Œπ‘‘βˆ˜π‘– 1Λ𝑖 ≀ ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽβˆ˜ ]1Λ𝑖

Ξ©.

𝜎=

βˆ‘π‘

𝑖=1 𝑑𝑖 1Λ𝑖 and that

It suces to show that

𝑃 -a.s.

for

1 ≀ 𝑖 ≀ 𝑁.

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽβˆ˜ ,𝑃 )

In the sequel, we x

𝑃¯ ∈

𝑖

and show that for each

𝒫(β„±πœŽβˆ˜ , 𝑃 ) such that 𝑃¯ (𝐴 ∩ Λ𝑖 ) = 𝑃 β€² (𝐴 ∩ Λ𝑖 )

In view of (4.1) and

𝑃 β€² ∈ 𝒫(β„±π‘‘βˆ˜π‘– , 𝑃 )

for all

𝐴 ∈ β„±π‘‡βˆ˜ .

(4.8)

β€²

β€²

there exists

𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽβˆ˜ ]1Λ𝑖 = 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±π‘‘βˆ˜π‘– ]1Λ𝑖 𝑃 β€² -a.s.,

it will then

follow that

Β―

β€²

π‘Œπ‘‘βˆ˜π‘– 1Λ𝑖 = ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋1Λ𝑖 βˆ£β„±π‘‘βˆ˜π‘– ] ≀ ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋1Λ𝑖 βˆ£β„±πœŽβˆ˜ ] 𝑃 -a.s. 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ,𝑃 ) 𝑖

𝑃¯ βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽβˆ˜ ,𝑃 )

as claimed. Indeed, given

𝑃 β€² ∈ 𝒫(β„±π‘‘βˆ˜π‘– , 𝑃 ),

we dene

𝑃¯ (𝐴) := 𝑃 β€² (𝐴 ∩ Λ𝑖 ) + 𝑃 (𝐴 βˆ– Λ𝑖 ),

𝐴 ∈ β„±π‘‡βˆ˜ ,

(4.9)

Ξ› ∈ β„±πœŽβˆ˜ , then Ξ› ∩ Λ𝑖 = Ξ› ∩ {𝜎 = 𝑑𝑖 } ∈ β„±π‘‘βˆ˜π‘– 𝑃 β€² (Ξ› ∩ Λ𝑖 ) = 𝑃 (Ξ› ∩ Λ𝑖 ). Hence 𝑃¯ = 𝑃 on β„±πœŽβˆ˜ .

then (4.8) is obviously satised. If and

𝑃 β€² ∈ 𝒫(β„±π‘‘βˆ˜π‘– , 𝑃 )

yields

Moreover, we observe that (4.9) can be stated as

] [ 𝑃¯ (𝐴) = 𝐸 𝑃 𝑃 β€² (π΄βˆ£β„±π‘‘βˆ˜π‘– )1Λ𝑖 + 𝑃 (π΄βˆ£β„±π‘‘βˆ˜π‘– )1Λ𝑐𝑖 ,

𝐴 ∈ β„±π‘‡βˆ˜ ,

which is a special case of the pasting (3.2) applied with

𝑃¯ ∈ 𝒫

by Assumption 4.1 and we have

𝑃¯ ∈ 𝒫(β„±πœŽβˆ˜ , 𝑃 )

𝑃2 := 𝑃 .

Hence

as desired.

For the next result, we recall that stability under pasting refers to stopping times with nitely many values rather than general ones (Denition 3.2).

Lemma 4.9. The set 𝒫 is stable under 𝔽-pasting. Proof. Let 𝜏 ∈ 𝒯 (𝔽), then 𝜏 is of the form 𝜏=

βˆ‘

𝑑𝑖 1Λ𝑖 ,

Λ𝑖 := {𝜏 = 𝑑𝑖 } ∈ ℱ𝑑𝑖 ,

𝑖

∈ [0, 𝑇 ] are distinct and the sets Λ𝑖 form a partition of Ξ©. Moreover, Ξ› ∈ β„± 𝜏 and 𝑃1 , 𝑃2 ∈ 𝒫(β„±πœ , ]𝑃 ), then we have to show that the measure [ 𝑃 𝐸 𝑃1 ( β‹… βˆ£β„±πœ )1Ξ› + 𝑃2 ( β‹… βˆ£β„±πœ )1Λ𝑐 is an element of 𝒫 .

where 𝑑𝑖 let

14

(i) We start by proving that for any such that

𝐴=

𝐴′ holds

𝐴 ∈ β„±πœ

𝒫(β„±πœ , 𝑃 )-q.s. Consider βˆͺ 𝐴 = (𝐴 ∩ Λ𝑖 ).

there exists

𝐴′ ∈ β„±π‘‡βˆ˜ ∩ β„±πœ

the disjoint union

𝑖

𝐴 ∩ Λ𝑖 ∈ ℱ𝑑𝑖 since 𝐴 ∈ β„±πœ . As F βŠ† π”½βˆ˜ by Lemma 4.4, 𝐴𝑖 ∈ β„±π‘‘βˆ˜π‘– and a 𝑃 -nullset 𝑁𝑖 , disjoint from 𝐴𝑖 , such that 𝑃

Here set

𝐴 ∩ Λ𝑖 = 𝐴𝑖 βˆͺ 𝑁𝑖 . (It is

not

there exist a

(4.10)

necessary to subtract another nullset on the right hand side.) We

𝐴′ := βˆͺ𝑖 𝐴𝑖 , then 𝐴′ ∈ β„±π‘‡βˆ˜ and clearly 𝐴 = 𝐴′ 𝑃 -a.s. Let us check that β€² latter also holds 𝒫(β„±πœ , 𝑃 )-q.s. For this, it suces to show that 𝐴 ∈ β„±πœ .

dene the

Indeed, by the construction of (4.10),

{ 𝐴𝑖 ∈ β„±π‘‘βˆ˜π‘– βŠ† ℱ𝑑𝑖 , 𝑖 = 𝑗, 𝐴𝑖 ∩ {𝜏 = 𝑑𝑗 } = βˆ… ∈ ℱ𝑑𝑗 , 𝑗= βˆ• 𝑖; i.e., each set

𝐴𝑖

is in

β„±πœ .

Hence,

𝐴′ ∈ β„±πœ ,

which completes the proof of (i).

∘ For later use, we dene the 𝔽 -stopping time

(𝜏𝐴 )∘ := 𝑇 1(𝐴′ )𝑐 +

βˆ‘

𝑑 𝑖 1𝐴 𝑖

𝑖

)∘

𝒫(β„±πœ , 𝑃 )-q.s. (ii) Using the previous construction for 𝐴 = Ξ©, we see in ∘ ∘ ∘ there exist Λ𝑖 ∈ ℱ𝑑 such that Λ𝑖 = Λ𝑖 holds 𝒫(β„±πœ , 𝑃 )-q.s. 𝑖 ∘ the 𝔽 -stopping time βˆ‘ 𝜏 ∘ := 𝑇 1(βˆͺ𝑖 Ξ›βˆ˜π‘– )𝑐 + 𝑑𝑖 1Ξ›βˆ˜π‘–

and note that

(𝜏𝐴

= 𝜏𝐴

holds

particular that We also dene

𝑖

𝜏∘ = 𝜏. ∘ (iii) We can now show that β„±πœ ∘ and β„±πœ may be identied (when 𝑃, 𝑃1 , 𝑃2 β€² are xed). Indeed, if 𝐴 ∈ β„±πœ , we let 𝐴 be as in (i) and set ( ) 𝐴∘ := 𝐴′ ∩ {𝜏 ∘ = 𝑇 } βˆͺ {(𝜏𝐴 )∘ = 𝜏 ∘ < 𝑇 }.

which

𝒫(β„±πœ , 𝑃 )-q.s.

satises

𝐴∘ ∈ β„±πœβˆ˜βˆ˜ and 𝐴 = 𝐴∘ holds 𝒫(β„±πœ , 𝑃 )-q.s. Conversely, given 𝐴∘ ∈ β„±πœβˆ˜βˆ˜ , ∘ we nd 𝐴 ∈ β„±πœ such that 𝐴 = 𝐴 holds 𝒫(β„±πœ , 𝑃 )-q.s. We conclude that ] [ ] [ 𝐸 𝑃 𝑃1 ( β‹… βˆ£β„±πœ )1Ξ› + 𝑃2 ( β‹… βˆ£β„±πœ )1Λ𝑐 = 𝐸 𝑃 𝑃1 ( β‹… βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜βˆ˜ )1Ξ›βˆ˜ + 𝑃2 ( β‹… βˆ£β„±πœβˆ˜βˆ˜ )1(Ξ›βˆ˜ )𝑐 . Then

The right hand side is an element of

𝒫

by the stability under

We can now prove the optional sampling theorem for particular, this establishes the

𝔽-time-consistency

stopping times.

15

of

{ℰ𝑑 }

π”½βˆ˜ -pasting.

β„° -martingales; along general

in

F-

Theorem 4.10. Let 0 ≀ 𝜎 ≀ 𝜏 ≀ 𝑇 be stopping times, β„°(𝑋) be the cΓ dlΓ g β„° -martingale associated with 𝑋 . Then 𝑃 -a.s.

β€²

β„°πœŽ (𝑋) = ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [β„°πœ (𝑋)βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽ ,𝑃 )

𝑋 ∈ β„‹,

and let

for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫

(4.11)

and in particular 𝑃 -a.s.

β€²

β„°πœŽ (𝑋) = ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽ ,𝑃 )

for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

(4.12)

Moreover, there exists for each 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 a sequence 𝑃𝑛 ∈ 𝒫(β„±πœŽ , 𝑃 ) such that 𝑃 -a.s.

β„°πœŽ (𝑋) = lim 𝐸 𝑃𝑛 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] π‘›β†’βˆž

(4.13)

with an increasing limit. Proof.

Fix

𝑃 βˆˆπ’«

and let

π‘Œ := β„°(𝑋).

(i) We rst show the inequality  β‰₯ in (4.12).

π‘Œ

is an

(F, 𝑃 β€² )-supermartingale

By Proposition 4.5(i),

𝑃 β€² ∈ 𝒫(β„±πœŽ , 𝑃 ).

for all

Hence the (usual)

optional sampling theorem implies the claim. (ii) In the next two steps, we show the inequality  ≀ in (4.12). In view of Lemma 4.7(ii) we may assume that

(𝜎 + 1/𝑛) ∧ 𝑇

𝜎

also assume that

𝜎

𝔽+ -stopping time, and then 𝑛 β‰₯ 1. For the time being, we

is an

∘ is an 𝔽 -stopping time for each

takes nitely many values. Let

𝐷𝑛 := {π‘˜2βˆ’π‘› : π‘˜ = 0, 1, . . . } βˆͺ {𝑇 } and dene

𝜎 𝑛 (πœ”) := inf{𝑑 ∈ 𝐷𝑛 : 𝑑 β‰₯ 𝜎(πœ”) + 1/𝑛} ∧ 𝑇. π”½βˆ˜ -stopping time taking nitely many values and 𝜎 𝑛 (πœ”) de𝑛 creases to 𝜎(πœ”) for all πœ” ∈ Ξ©. Since the range of {𝜎, (𝜎 )𝑛 } is countable, it ∘ follows from Proposition 4.5(ii) that β„°πœŽ 𝑛 (𝑋) β†’ π‘ŒπœŽ 𝑃 -a.s. Since βˆ₯𝑋βˆ₯𝐿1 < ∞,

Each

πœŽπ‘›

is an

𝒫

the backward supermartingale convergence theorem [9, Theorem V.30] implies that this convergence holds also in

𝐿1 (𝑃 )

and that

π‘ŒπœŽ = lim 𝐸 𝑃 [β„°πœŽβˆ˜π‘› (𝑋)βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] 𝑃 -a.s., π‘›β†’βˆž

where, by monotonicity, the a subsequence. sequence

𝑃 -a.s.

(4.14)

convergence holds without passing to

By Lemma 4.8 and Lemma 3.4, there exists for each

(π‘ƒπ‘˜π‘› )π‘˜β‰₯1

in

𝒫(β„±πœŽβˆ˜π‘› , 𝑃 )

such that β€²

𝑛

β„°πœŽβˆ˜π‘› (𝑋) = ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽβˆ˜π‘› ] = lim 𝐸 π‘ƒπ‘˜ [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽβˆ˜π‘› ] 𝑃 -a.s., π‘˜β†’βˆž

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽβˆ˜π‘› ,𝑃 )

where the limit is increasing. Moreover, using that

{ β„±πœŽ+𝑛+1 = 𝐴 ∈ β„±π‘‡βˆ˜ : 𝐴 ∩ {𝜎 𝑛+1 < 𝑑} ∈ β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ 16

for

} 0≀𝑑≀𝑇 ,

𝑛

a

𝜎 𝑛 > 𝜎 𝑛+1 on {𝜎 𝑛 < 𝑇 } is seen to imply that β„±πœŽ+𝑛+1 βŠ† β„±πœŽβˆ˜π‘› . 𝑛+1 and Lemma 4.7(ii) we conclude that with 𝜎 ≀ 𝜎

the fact that Together

𝒫 -q.s.

β„±πœŽ βŠ† β„±πœŽπ‘›+1 = β„±πœŽ+𝑛+1 βŠ† β„±πœŽβˆ˜π‘›

and hence

𝒫(β„±πœŽ , 𝑃 ) βŠ‡ 𝒫(β„±πœŽβˆ˜π‘› , 𝑃 ) (4.15)

for all

𝑛.

Now monotone convergence yields β€²

𝑛

𝐸 𝑃 [β„°πœŽβˆ˜π‘› (𝑋)βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] = lim 𝐸 π‘ƒπ‘˜ [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽ ]

≀ ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] 𝑃 -a.s.

π‘˜β†’βˆž

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽ ,𝑃 )

In view of (4.14), this ends the proof of (4.12) for

𝜎

taking nitely many

values. (ii') Now let

πœŽπ‘›

𝜎

be general. We approximate

𝜎

by the decreasing sequence

:= inf{𝑑 ∈ 𝐷𝑛 : 𝑑 β‰₯ 𝜎} ∧ 𝑇 of stopping times with nitely many values. β„°πœŽπ‘› (𝑋) ≑ π‘ŒπœŽπ‘› β†’ π‘ŒπœŽ 𝑃 -a.s. since π‘Œ is cΓ dlΓ g. The same arguments as

Then

for (4.14) show that

π‘ŒπœŽ = lim 𝐸 𝑃 [β„°πœŽπ‘› (𝑋)βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] 𝑃 -a.s.

(4.16)

π‘›β†’βˆž

By the two previous steps we have the representation (4.12) for Lemma 3.4, it follows from the stability under there exists for each

𝑛

a sequence

(π‘ƒπ‘˜π‘› )π‘˜β‰₯1

in

πœŽπ‘›.

As in

𝔽-pasting (Lemma 4.9) that 𝒫(β„±πœŽπ‘› , 𝑃 ) βŠ† 𝒫(β„±πœŽ , 𝑃 ) such

that β€²

𝑛

β„°πœŽπ‘› (𝑋) = ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽπ‘› ] = lim 𝐸 π‘ƒπ‘˜ [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽπ‘› ] 𝑃 -a.s., π‘˜β†’βˆž

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽπ‘› ,𝑃 )

where the limit is increasing and hence β€²

𝑛

𝐸 𝑃 [β„°πœŽπ‘› (𝑋)βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] = lim 𝐸 π‘ƒπ‘˜ [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽ ]

≀ ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] 𝑃 -a.s.

π‘˜β†’βˆž

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽ ,𝑃 )

Together with (4.16), this completes the proof of (4.12). (iii) We now prove (4.13). Since

𝜎

is general, the claim does not follow

from the stability under pasting. Instead, we use the construction of (ii'). Indeed, we have obtained

π‘ƒπ‘˜π‘› ∈ 𝒫(β„±πœŽπ‘› , 𝑃 )

such that

𝑛

π‘ŒπœŽ = lim lim 𝐸 π‘ƒπ‘˜ [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] 𝑃 -a.s. π‘›β†’βˆž π‘˜β†’βˆž

𝑛. Since 𝜎 𝑛 is an 𝔽-stopping time taking nitely many values and since β„±πœŽ βŠ† β„±πœŽπ‘› , it follows from the stability under 𝔽-pasting (applied to 𝜎 𝑛 ) that 𝑃′ β€² the set {𝐸 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] : 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫(β„±πœŽ 𝑛 , 𝑃 )} is 𝑃 -a.s. upward ltering, exactly as in the proof of Lemma 3.4. In view of 𝒫(β„±πœŽ 𝑛 , 𝑃 ) βŠ† 𝒫(β„±πœŽ 𝑛+1 , 𝑃 ), it follows (𝑁 ) ∈ 𝒫(β„± that for each 𝑁 β‰₯ 1 there exists 𝑃 𝜎 𝑁 , 𝑃 ) such that Fix

𝐸𝑃

(𝑁 )

𝑛

[π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] = max max 𝐸 π‘ƒπ‘˜ [π‘‹βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] 𝑃 -a.s. 1≀𝑛≀𝑁 1β‰€π‘˜β‰€π‘›

17

Since

𝒫(β„±πœŽπ‘ , 𝑃 ) βŠ† 𝒫(β„±πœŽ , 𝑃 ),

this yields the claim.

β„°πœŽ (𝑋) and β„°πœ (𝑋) as essential for 𝜏 . The inequality  ≀ is then

(iv) To prove (4.11), we rst express suprema by using (4.12) both for

𝜎

and

immediate. The converse inequality follows by a monotone convergence argument exactly as in the proof of Proposition 3.6(i), except that the increasing sequence is now obtained from (4.13) instead of Lemma 3.4.

4.3

Decomposition and 2BSDE for

β„° -Martingales

The next result contains the semimartingale decomposition of each

𝑃 βˆˆπ’«

β„°(𝑋)

under

and can be seen as an analogue of the optional decomposition [19]

used in mathematical nance.

In the context of

𝐺-expectations,

such a

result has also been referred to as  𝐺-martingale representation theorem; see [16, 34, 35, 37]. Those results are ultimately based on the PDE description of the

𝐺-expectation

and are more precise than ours; in particular, they

(𝐾 𝑃 )𝑃 βˆˆπ’« (but 1 see Remark 4.17). On the other hand, we obtain an 𝐿 -theory whereas those

provide a single increasing process

𝐾

results require more integrability for

rather than a family

𝑋.

Proposition 4.11. Let 𝑋 ∈ β„‹. There exist ∫ (i) an F-predictable process 𝑍 𝑋 with 0𝑇 βˆ£π‘π‘ π‘‹ ∣2 π‘‘βŸ¨π΅βŸ©π‘  < ∞ 𝒫 -q.s., (ii) a family (𝐾 𝑃 )𝑃 βˆˆπ’« of 𝔽𝑃 -predictable processes such that all paths of 𝐾 𝑃 are cΓ dlΓ g nondecreasing and 𝐸 𝑃 [βˆ£πΎπ‘‡π‘ƒ ∣] < ∞, such that (π‘ƒβˆ«) 𝑑

ℰ𝑑 (𝑋) = β„°0 (𝑋) +

𝑍𝑠𝑋 𝑑𝐡𝑠 βˆ’ 𝐾𝑑𝑃

0

for all 0 ≀ 𝑑 ≀ 𝑇, 𝑃 -a.s.

(4.17)

for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 . The process 𝑍 𝑋 is unique up to {𝑑𝑠 Γ— 𝑃, 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫}-polar sets and 𝐾 𝑃 is unique up to 𝑃 -evanescence. Proof. We shall use arguments similar to the proof of [33, Theorem 4.5]. Let

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

It follows from Proposition 4.5(i) that

π‘Œ := β„°(𝑋)

is an

𝑃

(𝔽 , 𝑃 )-supermartingale. We apply the Doob-Meyer decomposition in the 𝑃 ltered space (Ξ©, 𝔽 , 𝑃 ) which satises the usual conditions of right continu𝑃 𝑃 and ity and completeness. Thus we obtain an (𝔽 , 𝑃 )-local martingale 𝑀 𝑃 𝑃 an 𝔽 -predictable increasing integrable process 𝐾 , cΓ dlΓ g and satisfying 𝑀0𝑃 = 𝐾0𝑃 = 0, such that π‘Œ = π‘Œ0 + 𝑀 𝑃 βˆ’ 𝐾 𝑃 . (𝑃, 𝐡) has the predictable representation 𝑃 𝑃 such that exists an 𝔽 -predictable process 𝑍 (π‘ƒβˆ«) π‘Œ = π‘Œ0 + 𝑍 𝑃 𝑑𝐡 βˆ’ 𝐾 𝑃 .

By Lemma 4.4, Hence there

18

property in

𝑃

𝔽

.

The next step is to replace calling that

∫

𝐡

𝑍𝑃

by a process

𝑍𝑋

independent of

is a continuous local martingale under each

𝑍 𝑃 π‘‘βŸ¨π΅βŸ©π‘ƒ = βŸ¨π‘Œ, π΅βŸ©π‘ƒ = π΅π‘Œ βˆ’

(π‘ƒβˆ«)

𝑃,

𝑃.

Re-

we have

(π‘ƒβˆ«)

𝐡 π‘‘π‘Œ βˆ’

π‘Œβˆ’ 𝑑𝐡

𝑃 -a.s.

(4.18)

(Here and below, the statements should be read componentwise.) The last two integrals are ItΓ΄ integrals under

𝑃 , but they can also be dened pathwise

since the integrands are left limits of cΓ dlΓ g processes which are bounded path-by-path.

This is a classical construction from [3, Theorem 7.14]; see

also [18] for the same result in modern notation.

To make explicit that

∫the resulting process is 𝔽-adapted, we recall the procedure for the example π‘Œβˆ’ 𝑑𝐡 . One rst denes for each 𝑛 β‰₯ 1 the sequence of F-stopping times 𝑛 := inf{𝑑 β‰₯ 𝜏 𝑛 : βˆ£π‘Œ βˆ’ π‘Œ 𝑛 ∣ β‰₯ 2βˆ’π‘› }. Then one denes 𝐼 𝑛 by 𝜏0𝑛 := 0 and πœπ‘–+1 𝑑 πœπ‘– 𝑖 𝐼𝑑𝑛 := π‘Œπœπ‘˜π‘› (𝐡𝑑 βˆ’ π΅πœπ‘˜π‘› ) +

π‘˜βˆ’1 βˆ‘

𝑛 π‘Œπœπ‘–π‘› (π΅πœπ‘–+1 βˆ’ π΅πœπ‘–π‘› )

for

𝑛 πœπ‘˜π‘› < 𝑑 ≀ πœπ‘˜+1 ,

π‘˜ β‰₯ 0;

𝑖=0 clearly

𝐼𝑛

is again

F-adapted and all its paths are cΓ dlΓ g. Finally, we dene 𝐼𝑑 := lim sup 𝐼𝑑𝑛 ,

0 ≀ 𝑑 ≀ 𝑇.

π‘›β†’βˆž

Then

𝐼

is again

F-adapted and it is a consequence of the Burkholder-Davis-

Gundy inequalities that

∫ 𝑛 (𝑃 ) 𝑑 sup 𝐼𝑑 βˆ’ π‘Œβˆ’ 𝑑𝐡 β†’ 0 𝑃 -a.s.

0≀𝑑≀𝑇 for each

𝑃.

0

Thus, outside a

exists as a limit uniformly in

𝒫 -polar 𝑑 and 𝐼

set, the limsup in the denition of has cΓ dlΓ g paths. Since

𝒫 -polar

𝐼

sets

β„±0 , we may redene 𝐼 := 0 on the exceptional set. Now ∫ 𝐼 is cΓ dlΓ g F-adapted and coincides with the ItΓ΄ integral (𝑃 ) π‘Œβˆ’ 𝑑𝐡 up to 𝑃 -evanescence, for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 . ∫ (𝑃 ) 𝐡 π‘‘π‘Œ and obtain a denition We proceed similarly with the integral

are contained in

for the right hand side of (4.18) which is

F-adapted, continuous and inde-

βŸ¨π‘Œ, 𝐡⟩ simultaneously for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 , π‘Ž Λ† = π‘‘βŸ¨π΅βŸ©/𝑑𝑑 be the (left) derivative in time of ⟨𝐡⟩, then π‘Ž Λ† is π”½βˆ˜ -predictable and π•Š>0 𝑑 -valued 𝑃 Γ— 𝑑𝑑-a.e. for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 𝑋 by the denition of 𝒫𝑆 . Finally, 𝑍 := π‘Ž Λ†βˆ’1 π‘‘βŸ¨π‘Œ, 𝐡⟩/𝑑𝑑 is an F-predictable

pendent of

𝑃.

Thus we have dened

and we do the same for

⟨𝐡⟩.

Let

process such that

(π‘ƒβˆ«)

π‘Œ = π‘Œ0 +

𝑍 𝑋 𝑑𝐡 βˆ’ 𝐾 𝑃

We note that the integral is taken under to dene it for all

𝑃 βˆˆπ’«

simultaneously.

19

𝑃 -a.s. 𝑃;

for all

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

see also Remark 4.17 for a way

The previous proof shows that a decomposition of the type (4.17) ex-

(𝔽, 𝒫)-supermartingales,

ists for all cΓ dlΓ g

and not just for

β„° -martingales.

As a special case of Proposition 4.11, we obtain a representation for symmetric

β„° -martingales.

The following can be seen as a generalization of the

corresponding results for

𝐺-expectations

given in [34, 35, 37].

Corollary 4.12. Let 𝑋 ∈ β„‹ be such that βˆ’π‘‹ ∈ β„‹. The following are equivalent: (i) β„°(𝑋) is a symmetric β„° -martingale; i.e., β„°(βˆ’π‘‹) = βˆ’β„°(𝑋) 𝒫 -q.s. ∫ (ii) There exists an F-predictable process 𝑍 𝑋 with 0𝑇 βˆ£π‘π‘ π‘‹ ∣2 π‘‘βŸ¨π΅βŸ©π‘  < ∞ 𝒫 -q.s. such that 𝑑

∫

𝑍𝑠𝑋 𝑑𝐡𝑠

ℰ𝑑 (𝑋) = β„°0 (𝑋) + 0

for all 0 ≀ 𝑑 ≀ 𝑇, 𝒫 -q.s.,

where the integral can be dened universally for all 𝑃 and 𝑍 𝑋 𝑑𝐡 is an (𝔽, 𝑃 )-martingale for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 . In particular, any symmetric β„° -martingale has continuous trajectories 𝒫 -q.s. ∫

Proof.

The implication (ii)β‡’(i) is clear from Proposition 4.5(iii).

Con-

β„°(𝑋) and βˆ’β„°(𝑋) are 𝒫 -martingale. It follows that 𝑃 ≑ 0 and (4.17) becomes satisfy 𝐾

versely, given (i), Proposition 4.5(i) yields that both

𝒫 -supermartingales,

hence

β„°(𝑋)

is a (true)

𝐾 𝑃 have to 𝑑𝐡 . ∫In particular, the stochastic setting 𝑍 𝑋 𝑑𝐡 := β„°(𝑋) βˆ’ β„°0 (𝑋).

the increasing processes

(𝑃 )

∫

β„°(𝑋) = β„°0 (𝑋) +

dened universally by

Remark 4.13.

𝑍𝑋

integral can be

(a) Without the martingale condition in Corollary 4.12(ii),

the implication (ii)β‡’(i) would fail even for

𝒫 = {𝑃0 },

in which case Corol-

lary 4.12 is simply the Brownian martingale representation theorem.

β„°(𝑋) need not be a 𝒫 -modication of the fam𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ]}; in fact, the β„° -martingale in Example 4.6 is symmetric.

(b) Even if it is symmetric,

∘ ily {ℰ𝑑 (𝑋),

However, the situation changes if the symmetry assumption is imposed di-

{β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋)}. 𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ].

rectly on for all

βˆ™

We call

{β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋)} symmetric if β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (βˆ’π‘‹) = βˆ’β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋) 𝒫 -q.s.

If {β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋)} symmetric, then β„°(𝑋) is a symmetric β„° -martingale and a 𝒫 -modication of {β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋)}.

Indeed, the assumption implies that each

𝑃 βˆˆπ’«

and so the process

is the usual cΓ dlΓ g

β„°(𝑋)

𝑃 -modication

Next, we represent the pair

of

{β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋)}

is an

(π”½βˆ˜ , 𝑃 )-martingale

for

of right limits (cf. Proposition 4.5(ii))

{β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋)},

(β„°(𝑋), 𝑍 𝑋 )

for all

𝑃.

from Proposition 4.11 as the

solution of a 2BSDE. The following denition is essentially from [32].

Denition 4.14. values in

ℝ Γ— ℝ𝑑

Let

such

𝑋 ∈ 𝐿1𝒫 and consider a pair (π‘Œ, 𝑍) of processes with that π‘Œ is cΓ dlΓ g F-adapted while 𝑍 is F-predictable 20

and

βˆ«π‘‡

βˆ£π‘π‘  ∣2 π‘‘βŸ¨π΅βŸ©π‘  < ∞ 𝒫 -q.s.

0

Then

(π‘Œ, 𝑍)

is called a

𝑃 2BSDE (4.19) if there exists a family (𝐾 )𝑃 βˆˆπ’« of 𝑃 𝑃 processes satisfying 𝐸 [βˆ£πΎπ‘‡ ∣] < ∞ such that (π‘ƒβˆ«) 𝑇

π‘Œπ‘‘ = 𝑋 βˆ’

𝑍𝑠 𝑑𝐡𝑠 + 𝐾𝑇𝑃 βˆ’ 𝐾𝑑𝑃 ,

0 ≀ 𝑑 ≀ 𝑇,

𝑃

𝔽

solution

of the

-adapted increasing

𝑃 -a.s.

for all

𝑃 βˆˆπ’«

𝑑 (4.19) and such that the following minimality condition holds for all

ess inf 𝑃

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(ℱ𝑑 ,𝑃 )

] β€²[ β€² β€² 𝐸 𝑃 𝐾𝑇𝑃 βˆ’ 𝐾𝑑𝑃 ℱ𝑑 = 0 𝑃 -a.s.

We note that (4.20) is essentially the

for all

0 ≀ 𝑑 ≀ 𝑇:

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

β„° -martingale condition (4.4):

(4.20)

if the

𝑃 can be aggregated into a single process 𝐾 and 𝐾 ∈ β„‹, then processes 𝐾 𝑇 βˆ’πΎ = β„°(βˆ’πΎπ‘‡ ). Regarding the aggregation of (𝐾 𝑃 ), see also Remark 4.17. A second notion is needed to state the main result.

π‘Œ

is said to be

under

𝑃

for all

of class (D,𝒫 )

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫,

where

if the family

𝜎

{π‘ŒπœŽ }𝜎

runs through all

A cΓ dlΓ g process

is uniformly integrable

F-stopping times.

example, we have seen in Corollary 4.12 that all symmetric

As an

β„° -martingales

are of class (D,𝒫 ). (Of course, it is important here that we work with a nite

𝑇 .) For 𝑝 ∈ [1, ∞), we 𝑝 β„‹ := {𝑋 ∈ β„‹ : βˆ£π‘‹βˆ£π‘ ∈ β„‹}.

time horizon well as

dene

βˆ₯𝑋βˆ₯𝐿𝑝 =: sup𝑃 βˆˆπ’« 𝐸[βˆ£π‘‹βˆ£π‘ ]1/𝑝 𝒫

as

Lemma 4.15. If 𝑋 ∈ ℋ𝑝 for some 𝑝 ∈ (1, ∞), then β„°(𝑋) is of class (D,𝒫 ). Proof.

Let

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

If

𝜎

is an

F-stopping time, Jensen's inequality and (4.12)

yield that β€²

βˆ£β„°πœŽ (𝑋)βˆ£π‘ ≀ ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [βˆ£π‘‹βˆ£π‘ βˆ£β„±πœŽ ] = β„°πœŽ (βˆ£π‘‹βˆ£π‘ ) 𝑃 -a.s. 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±πœŽ ,𝑃 )

In particular,

βˆ₯β„°πœŽ (𝑋)βˆ₯𝑝𝐿𝑝 (𝑃 ) ≀ 𝐸 𝑃 [β„°πœŽ (βˆ£π‘‹βˆ£π‘ )]

and thus Lemma 4.4 yields β€²

βˆ₯β„°πœŽ (𝑋)βˆ₯𝑝𝐿𝑝 (𝑃 ) ≀ 𝐸 𝑃 [β„°πœŽ (βˆ£π‘‹βˆ£π‘ )βˆ£β„±0 ] ≀ ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [β„°πœŽ (βˆ£π‘‹βˆ£π‘ )βˆ£β„±0 ] 𝑃 -a.s. 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±0 ,𝑃 )

The right hand side

𝑃 -a.s. equals β„°0 (βˆ£π‘‹βˆ£π‘ ) by (4.11), so we conclude with (4.7)

that β€²

βˆ₯β„°πœŽ (𝑋)βˆ₯𝑝𝐿𝑝 (𝑃 ) ≀ β„°0 (βˆ£π‘‹βˆ£π‘ ) ≀ sup 𝐸 𝑃 [βˆ£π‘‹βˆ£π‘ ] = βˆ₯𝑋βˆ₯𝑝𝐿𝑝 < ∞ 𝑃 -a.s. 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«

{β„°πœŽ (𝑋)}𝜎 is bounded in 𝐿𝑝 (𝑃 ) under 𝑃 . This holds for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 .

Therefore, the family formly integrable

We can now state the main result of this section.

21

𝒫

and in particular uni-

Theorem 4.16. Let 𝑋 ∈ β„‹. (i) The pair (β„°(𝑋), 𝑍 𝑋 ) is the minimal solution of the 2BSDE (4.19); i.e., if (π‘Œ, 𝑍) is another solution, then β„°(𝑋) ≀ π‘Œ 𝒫 -q.s. (ii) If (π‘Œ, 𝑍) is a solution of (4.19) such that π‘Œ is of class (D,𝒫 ), then (π‘Œ, 𝑍) = (β„°(𝑋), 𝑍 𝑋 ). In particular, if 𝑋 ∈ ℋ𝑝 for some 𝑝 > 1, then (β„°(𝑋), 𝑍 𝑋 ) is the unique solution of (4.19) in the class (D,𝒫 ). Proof. (i) Let 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 . To show that (β„°(𝑋), 𝑍 𝑋 ) is a solution, we only have to show that

𝐾𝑃

from the decomposition (4.17) satises the minimality con-

dition (4.20). We denote this decomposition by

β„°(𝑋)

It follows from Proposition 4.5(i) that As

𝐾 𝑃 β‰₯ 0,

is

β„°(𝑋) = β„°0 (𝑋) + 𝑀 𝑃 βˆ’ 𝐾 𝑃 . 𝑃 an (𝔽 , 𝑃 )-supermartingale.

we deduce that

𝑃

β„°0 (𝑋) + 𝑀 𝑃 β‰₯ β„°(𝑋) β‰₯ 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£π”½ ] 𝑃 -a.s., 𝑃

𝑃

𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£π”½ ] denotes the cΓ dlΓ g (𝔽 , 𝑃 )-martingale with terminal value 𝑋 . Hence 𝑀 𝑃 is a local 𝑃 -martingale bounded from below by a 𝑃 -martingale 𝑃 is an (F, 𝑃 )-supermartingale by a standard argument using and thus 𝑀 Fatou's lemma. This holds for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 . Therefore, (4.4) yields where

β€²

0 = ℰ𝑑 (𝑋) βˆ’ ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±π‘‘ ] 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(β„±

= ess inf

𝑃

𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(ℱ𝑑 ,𝑃 )

𝐸

𝑃′

[

𝑑 ,𝑃 )

] ℰ𝑑 (𝑋) βˆ’ ℰ𝑇 (𝑋) ℱ𝑑

] β€² β€² β€² β€²[ β€² = ess inf 𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 𝑀𝑑𝑃 βˆ’ 𝑀𝑇𝑃 + 𝐾𝑇𝑃 βˆ’ 𝐾𝑑𝑃 ℱ𝑑 β€² 𝑃 βˆˆπ’«(ℱ𝑑 ,𝑃 ) ] β€²[ β€² β€² β‰₯ ess inf 𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 𝐾𝑇𝑃 βˆ’ 𝐾𝑑𝑃 ℱ𝑑 𝑃 -a.s. for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫. 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(ℱ𝑑 ,𝑃 )

Since

𝐾𝑃

β€²

is nondecreasing, the last expression is also nonnegative and (4.20)

follows. Thus

(β„°(𝑋), 𝑍 𝑋 )

is a solution.

(π‘Œ, 𝑍) be another solution of (4.19). It (F, 𝑃 )-supermartingale for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 . ∫ (𝑃 ) As above, the integrability of 𝑋 implies that π‘Œ0 + 𝑍 𝑑𝐡 is bounded below by a 𝑃 -martingale. Noting also that π‘Œ0 is 𝑃 -a.s. equal to a constant ∫ (𝑃 ) 𝑍 𝑑𝐡 and π‘Œ are (F, 𝑃 )-supermartingales. by Lemma 4.4, we deduce that Since π‘Œ is cΓ dlΓ g and π‘Œπ‘‡ = 𝑋 , the minimality property in Proposition 4.5(i) shows that π‘Œ β‰₯ β„°(𝑋) 𝒫 -q.s. ∫ (𝑃 ) 𝑍 𝑑𝐡 is a true 𝑃 -martingale (ii) If in addition π‘Œ is of class (D,𝒫 ), then To prove the minimality, let

follows from (4.19) that

π‘Œ

is a local

by the Doob-Meyer theorem and we have

] β€²[ β€² β€² 0 = ess inf 𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 𝐾𝑇𝑃 βˆ’ 𝐾𝑑𝑃 ℱ𝑑 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(ℱ𝑑 ,𝑃 )

β€²

= π‘Œπ‘‘ βˆ’ ess sup𝑃 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘‹βˆ£β„±π‘‘ ] 𝑃 β€² βˆˆπ’«(ℱ𝑑 ,𝑃 )

= π‘Œπ‘‘ βˆ’ ℰ𝑑 (𝑋) 𝑃 -a.s. 22

for all

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

The last statement in the theorem follows from Lemma 4.15.

Remark 4.17.

If we use axioms of set theory stronger than the usual ZFC,

such as the Continuum Hypothesis, then the integrals

∫ {(𝑃 ) 𝑍 𝑑𝐡}𝑃 βˆˆπ’«

can

be aggregated into a single (universally measurable) continuous process, denoted by

∫

𝑍 𝑑𝐡 ,

for any

𝑍

which is

𝐡 -integrable

under all

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

This

follows from a recent result on pathwise stochastic integration, cf. [25]. In

(𝐾 𝑃 )𝑃 βˆˆπ’« of increasing ∫ 𝐾 := β„°0 (𝑋) βˆ’ β„°(𝑋) + 𝑍 𝑋 𝑑𝐡 .

Proposition 4.11, we can then aggregate the family processes into a single process

𝐾

by setting

Moreover, we can strengthen Theorem 4.16 by asking for a universal process

𝐾

the Denition 4.14 of the 2BSDE.

4.4

Application to Superhedging and Replication

We now turn to the interpretation of the previous results for the super-

𝑑 problem. Let 𝐻 be an ℝ -valued 𝔽-predictable process satisfying ∫hedging 𝑇 2 ∣ π‘‘βŸ¨π΅βŸ©π‘  < ∞ 𝒫 -q.s. Then 𝐻 is called an admissible trading strategy 0 ∣𝐻 βˆ«π‘  (𝑃 ) if 𝐻 𝑑𝐡 is a 𝑃 -supermartingale for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 . (We do not insist that the integral be dened without reference to 𝑃 , since this is not necessary economically.

But see also Remark 4.17.)

As usual in continuous-time -

nance, this denition excludes doubling strategies. proof of Theorem 4.16 that

𝑍𝑋

is admissible for

We have seen in the

𝑋 ∈ β„‹.

The minimality

property in Proposition 4.5(i) and the existence of the decomposition (4.17) yield the following conclusion:

β„°0 (𝑋) is the minimal β„±0 -measurable initial 𝑋 ; i.e., β„°0 (𝑋) is the 𝒫 -q.s. minimal β„±0 -

capital which allows to superhedge measurable random variable

𝐻

πœ‰0

such that there exists an admissible strategy

satisfying

(π‘ƒβˆ«) 𝑇

𝐻𝑠 𝑑𝐡𝑠 β‰₯ 𝑋

πœ‰0 +

𝑃 -a.s.

for all

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

0 Moreover, the overshoot

𝐾𝑃

for the strategy

𝑍𝑋

satises the minimality

condition (4.20). As seen in Example 4.6, the

β„±0 -superhedging

price

β„°0 (𝑋)

need not be

a constant, and therefore it is debatable whether it is a good choice for a conservative price, in particular if the raw ltration

π”½βˆ˜

is seen as the initial

information structure for the model. Indeed, the following illustration shows that knowledge of

β„±0

can be quite signicant. Consider a collection

positive constants and

𝒫 = {𝑃 𝛼 : 𝛼 ≑ π‘Žπ‘–

for some

𝑖}.

(Such a set

(π‘Žπ‘– ) of 𝒫 can

indeed satisfy the assumptions of this section.) In this model, knowledge of

β„±0

β„±0 contains { } ∘ 𝐴𝑖 := lim sup π‘‘βˆ’1 βŸ¨π΅βŸ©π‘‘ = lim inf π‘‘βˆ’1 βŸ¨π΅βŸ©π‘‘ = π‘Žπ‘– ∈ β„±0+

completely removes the volatility uncertainty since

𝑑→0

𝑑→0

23

the sets

which form a

𝒫 -q.s.

partition of

Ξ©.

Hence, one may want to use the more

conservative choice

π‘₯ = β„°0∘ (𝑋) = sup 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋] = inf{𝑦 ∈ ℝ : 𝑦 β‰₯ β„°0 (𝑋)} 𝑃 βˆˆπ’«

β„° -martingale as follows. β„±0βˆ’ be the smallest 𝜎 -eld containing the 𝒫 -polar sets, then β„±0βˆ’ is trivial 𝒫 -q.s. If we adjoin β„±0βˆ’ as a new initial state to the ltration 𝔽, we can extend β„°(𝑋) by setting as the price. This value can be embedded into the

Let

β„°0βˆ’ (𝑋) := sup 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋],

𝑋 ∈ β„‹.

𝑃 βˆˆπ’« The resulting process

{ℰ𝑑 (𝑋)}π‘‘βˆˆ[βˆ’0,𝑇 ]

satises the properties from Proposi-

π‘₯ = β„°0βˆ’ (𝑋) β„±0βˆ’ -superhedging price of 𝑋 . (Of course, all this becomes superuous ∘ the case where β„°(𝑋) is a 𝒫 -modication of {ℰ𝑑 (𝑋)}.)

tion 4.5 in the extended ltration and in particular the constant is the in

In the remainder of the section, we discuss replicable claims and adopt the previously mentioned conservative choice.

Denition 4.18. a constant

𝒫 -q.s.

π‘₯βˆˆβ„

A random variable and an

𝑋 ∈ β„‹ is called replicable if there exist βˆ«π‘‡ 2 π‘‘βŸ¨π΅βŸ© < ∞ ∣𝐻 ∣ 𝑠 𝑠 0

F-predictable process 𝐻 with

such that

(π‘ƒβˆ«) 𝑇

𝑋 =π‘₯+

𝐻𝑑 𝑑𝐡𝑑

𝑃 -a.s.

for all

𝑃 βˆˆπ’«

(4.21)

0 and such that

(𝑃 )

∫

𝐻 𝑑𝐡

is an

(F, 𝑃 )-martingale

for all

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫.

The martingale assumption is needed to avoid strategies which throw away money. Moreover, as in Corollary 4.12, the stochastic integral can necessarily be dened without reference to

𝑃,

by setting

∫

𝐻 𝑑𝐡 := β„°(𝑋) βˆ’ π‘₯.

The following result is an analogue of the standard characterization of replicable claims in incomplete markets (e.g., [8, p. 182]).

Proposition 4.19. Let 𝑋 ∈ β„‹ be such that βˆ’π‘‹ ∈ β„‹. The following are equivalent: (i) β„°(𝑋) is a symmetric β„° -martingale and β„°0 (𝑋) is constant 𝒫 -q.s. (ii) 𝑋 is replicable. (iii) There exists π‘₯ ∈ ℝ such that 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋] = π‘₯ for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 . Proof.

The equivalence (i)⇔(ii) is immediate from Corollary 4.12 and the

implication (ii)β‡’(iii) follows by taking expectations in (4.21). prove (iii)β‡’(ii).

By (4.7) we have

Hence we

β„°0 (βˆ’π‘‹) ≀ sup𝑃 βˆˆπ’« 𝐸 𝑃 [βˆ’π‘‹] = βˆ’π‘₯

24

and

β„°(𝑋) ≀ π‘₯. Thus, β„°(𝑋) show that (π‘ƒβˆ«) 𝑇 𝑍 βˆ’π‘‹ 𝑑𝐡 βˆ’π‘‹ ≀ βˆ’π‘₯ +

similarly

β„°(βˆ’π‘‹)

𝑃 ∈ 𝒫,

given

the decompositions (4.17) of

and

(π‘ƒβˆ«) 𝑇

𝑋 ≀π‘₯+

and

𝑍 𝑋 𝑑𝐡

𝑃 -a.s.

(4.22)

0

0

∫ (𝑃 ) 𝑇 (𝑍 βˆ’π‘‹ 0

+ 𝑍 𝑋 ) 𝑑𝐡 𝑃 -a.s. As we 𝑋 and 𝑍 βˆ’π‘‹ know from the proof of Theorem 4.16 that the integrals of 𝑍 ∫ ∫ 𝑇 𝑇 (𝑃 ) βˆ’π‘‹ 𝑑𝐡 = βˆ’(𝑃 ) 𝑋 are supermartingales, it follows that 0 𝑍 0 𝑍 𝑑𝐡 𝑃 -a.s. ∫ 𝑇 (𝑃 ) 𝑋 Now (4.22) yields that 𝑋 = π‘₯ + 0 𝑍 𝑑𝐡 . In view of (iii), this integral

Adding the inequalities yields

0 ≀

is a supermartingale with constant expectation, hence a martingale.

5

Uniqueness of Time-Consistent Extensions

In the introduction, we have claimed that

{β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ (𝑋)}

as in (1.2) is the natural

dynamic extension of the static sublinear expectation

𝑋 7β†’ sup𝑃 βˆˆπ’« 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋].

In this section, we add some substance to this claim by showing that the extension is unique under suitable assumptions. (We note that by Proposition 3.6, the question of existence is essentially reduced to the technical problem of aggregation.) The setup is as follows. We x a nonempty set on

(Ξ©, β„±π‘‡βˆ˜ ); it is not important whether 𝒫

𝒫

of probability measures

consists of martingale laws. On the

other hand, we impose additional structure on the set of random variables. In this section, we consider a chain of vector spaces

ℝ = β„‹0 βŠ† ℋ𝑠 βŠ† ℋ𝑑 βŠ† ℋ𝑇 =: β„‹ βŠ† 𝐿1𝒫 , We assume that addition

π‘Œ

𝑋, π‘Œ ∈ ℋ𝑑

implies

is bounded. As before,

(ℋ𝑑 )0≀𝑑≀𝑇

satisfying

0 ≀ 𝑠 ≀ 𝑑 ≀ 𝑇.

𝑋 ∧ π‘Œ, 𝑋 ∨ π‘Œ ∈ ℋ𝑑 , and π‘‹π‘Œ ∈ ℋ𝑑 if in β„‹ should be seen as the set of nancial

ℋ𝑑 will serve as test functions; the main example ℋ𝑑 = β„‹ ∩ 𝐿1𝒫 (β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ). We consider a family (𝔼𝑑 )0≀𝑑≀𝑇 of

claims. The elements of to have in mind is mappings

𝔼𝑑 : β„‹ β†’ 𝐿1𝒫 (β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ) (𝔼𝑑 ) as a dynamic extension of 𝔼0 . Our aim is to nd conditions under which 𝔼0 already determines the whole family (𝔼𝑑 ), or more precisely, determines 𝔼𝑑 (𝑋) up to a 𝒫 -polar set for all 𝑋 ∈ β„‹ and 0 ≀ 𝑑 ≀ 𝑇 .

and think of

Denition 5.1. if for all

(𝔼𝑑 )0≀𝑑≀𝑇 𝑋 ∈ β„‹,

The family

𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ]

and

𝔼𝑑 (π‘‹πœ‘) = 𝔼𝑑 (𝑋)πœ‘ 𝒫 -q.s.

is called

(ℋ𝑑 )-positively

for all bounded nonnegative

Note that this property excludes trivial extensions of

𝔼0 ,

we can always dene the (time-consistent) extension

{ 𝔼0 (𝑋), 0 ≀ 𝑑 < 𝑇, 𝔼𝑑 (𝑋) := 𝑋, 𝑑 = 𝑇, 25

𝔼0 .

homogeneous πœ‘ ∈ ℋ𝑑 . Indeed, given

but this family choices of

(𝔼𝑑 )

is not

(ℋ𝑑 )-positively

homogeneous for nondegenerate

(ℋ𝑑 ).

To motivate the next denition, we rst recall that in the classical setup under a reference measure

π‘ƒβˆ— ,

strict monotonicity of

tion for uniqueness of extensions; i.e., should imply that

𝔼0 (𝑋) > 𝔼0 (π‘Œ ).

𝔼0 is the crucial condi𝑋 β‰₯ π‘Œ π‘ƒβˆ— -a.s. and π‘ƒβˆ— {𝑋 > π‘Œ } > 0

In our setup with singular measures,

𝔼0 (β‹…) = sup𝑃 βˆˆπ’« 𝐸 𝑃 [ β‹… ], it is completely reasonable to have random variables 𝑋 β‰₯ π‘Œ satisfying 𝔼0 (𝑋) = 𝔼0 (π‘Œ ) and 𝑃1 {𝑋 > π‘Œ } > 0 for some 𝑃1 ∈ 𝒫 , since the suprema can be attained at some 𝑃2 ∈ 𝒫 whose support is disjoint from {𝑋 > π‘Œ }. the corresponding condition is too strong. E.g., for

In the following denition, we allow for an additional localization by a test function.

Denition 5.2.

(ℋ𝑑 )-locally strictly monotone if for every 𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ] and any 𝑋, π‘Œ ∈ ℋ𝑑 satisfying 𝑋 β‰₯ π‘Œ 𝒫 -q.s. and 𝑃 (𝑋 > π‘Œ ) > 0 for some 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 , there exists 𝑓 ∈ ℋ𝑑 such that 0 ≀ 𝑓 ≀ 1 and We say that

𝔼0

is

𝔼0 (𝑋𝑓 ) > 𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 ). Here the delicate point is the regularity required for tempted to try

𝑓.

Indeed, one is

𝑓 := 1{𝑋>π‘Œ +𝛿} (for some constant 𝛿 > 0), but in applications ℋ𝑑 may exclude this choice and require a more rened

the denition of

construction. We defer this task to Proposition 5.5 and rst show how local strict monotonicity yields uniqueness.

Proposition 5.3. Let 𝔼0 be (ℋ𝑑 )-locally strictly monotone. Then there exists at most one extension of 𝔼0 to a family (𝔼𝑑 )0≀𝑑≀𝑇 which is (ℋ𝑑 )-positively homogeneous and satises 𝔼𝑑 (β„‹) βŠ† ℋ𝑑 and 𝔼0 ∘ 𝔼𝑑 = 𝔼0 on β„‹. ˜ 𝑑 ) be two such extensions and suppose for contradicProof. Let (𝔼𝑑 ) and (𝔼 ˜ 𝑑 (𝑋) for some 𝑋 ∈ β„‹; i.e., there exists 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 such that 𝔼𝑑 (𝑋) βˆ•= 𝔼 ˜ 𝑑 (𝑋)} > 0 or 𝑃 {𝔼𝑑 (𝑋) < 𝔼 ˜ 𝑑 (𝑋)} > 0. Without loss of 𝑃 {𝔼𝑑 (𝑋) > 𝔼

tion that either

generality, we focus on the rst case. Dene

πœ‘ := Then over,

([ ] ) ˜ 𝑑 (𝑋) ∨ 0 ∧ 1. 𝔼𝑑 (𝑋) βˆ’ 𝔼

πœ‘ ∈ ℋ𝑑 , since ℋ𝑑 is a lattice containing the constant functions; more˜ 𝑑 (𝑋)}. Setting 𝑋 β€² := π‘‹πœ‘ and 0 ≀ πœ‘ ≀ 1 and {πœ‘ = 0} = {𝔼𝑑 (𝑋) ≀ 𝔼

using the positive homogeneity, we arrive at

˜ 𝑑 (𝑋 β€² ) 𝔼𝑑 (𝑋 β€² ) β‰₯ 𝔼

and

{ } ˜ 𝑑 (𝑋 β€² ) > 0. 𝑃 𝔼𝑑 (𝑋 β€² ) > 𝔼

𝑓 ∈ ℋ𝑑 such that 0 ≀ 𝑓 ≀ 1 ( ) ( ) ˜ 𝑑 (𝑋 β€² )𝑓 . Now 𝔼0 = 𝔼0 ∘ 𝔼𝑑 yields that 𝔼0 𝔼𝑑 (𝑋 β€² )𝑓 > 𝔼0 𝔼 ( ) ( ) ˜ 𝑑 (𝑋 β€² )𝑓 = 𝔼 ˜ 0 (𝑋 β€² 𝑓 ), 𝔼0 (𝑋 β€² 𝑓 ) = 𝔼0 𝔼𝑑 (𝑋 β€² )𝑓 > 𝔼0 𝔼 By local strict monotonicity there exists

which contradicts

˜0. 𝔼0 = 𝔼 26

and

We can extend the previous result by applying it on dense subspaces. This relaxes the assumption that

𝔼𝑑 (β„‹) βŠ† ℋ𝑑

and simplies the verication

of local strict monotonicity since one can choose convenient spaces of test

Λ† 𝑑 )0≀𝑑≀𝑇 satisfying the same assump(β„‹ Λ† 𝑇 is a βˆ₯ β‹… βˆ₯ 1 -dense subspace of β„‹. We β„‹ 𝐿

functions. Consider a chain of spaces

(ℋ𝑑 )0≀𝑑≀𝑇 that (𝔼𝑑 )0≀𝑑≀𝑇

tions as say

and such that

𝒫

𝐿1𝒫 -continuous if ( ) ( ) 𝔼𝑑 : β„‹, βˆ₯ β‹… βˆ₯𝐿1 β†’ 𝐿1𝒫 (β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ ), βˆ₯ β‹… βˆ₯𝐿1 is

𝒫

𝒫

is continuous for every 𝑑. We remark that the motivating example

(β„°π‘‘βˆ˜ ) from

Assumption 4.1 satises this property (it is even Lipschitz continuous).

Corollary 5.4. Let 𝔼0 be (β„‹Λ† 𝑑 )-locally strictly monotone. Then there exists at most one extension of 𝔼0 to an 𝐿1𝒫 -continuous family (𝔼𝑑 )0≀𝑑≀𝑇 on Λ† 𝑑 )-positively homogeneous and satises 𝔼𝑑 (β„‹ ˆ𝑇 ) βŠ† β„‹ Λ† 𝑑 and β„‹ which is (β„‹ ˆ𝑇 . 𝔼0 ∘ 𝔼𝑑 = 𝔼0 on β„‹ Proof.

ˆ𝑇 . 𝔼𝑑 (𝑋) is uniquely determined for 𝑋 ∈ β„‹ Λ† 𝑇 βŠ† β„‹ is dense and 𝔼𝑑 is continuous, 𝔼𝑑 is also determined on β„‹. Since β„‹ Proposition 5.3 shows that

𝔼0 (β‹…) = sup𝑃 βˆˆπ’« 𝐸 𝑃 [ β‹… ]

In our last result, we show that

is

(ℋ𝑑 )-locally

strictly monotone in certain cases. The idea here is that we already have an

(𝔼𝑑 ) (as in Assumption 4.1), whose uniqueness we try to establish. 𝐢𝑏 (Ξ©) the set of bounded continuous functions on Ξ© and by ∘ 𝐢𝑏 (Ω𝑑 ) the ℱ𝑑 -measurable functions in 𝐢𝑏 (Ξ©), or equivalently the bounded functions which are continuous with respect to βˆ₯πœ”βˆ₯𝑑 := sup0≀𝑠≀𝑑 βˆ£πœ”π‘  ∣. Similarly, UC𝑏 (Ξ©) and UC𝑏 (Ω𝑑 ) denote the sets of bounded uniformly continuous 1 1 ∞ functions. We also dene 𝕃𝑐,𝒫 to be the closure of 𝐢𝑏 (Ξ©) in 𝐿𝒫 , while 𝕃𝑐,𝒫 1 ∞ ∘ denotes the 𝒫 -q.s. bounded elements of 𝕃𝑐,𝒫 . Finally, 𝕃𝑐,𝒫 (ℱ𝑑 ) is obtained ∞ ∘ similarly from 𝐢𝑏 (Ω𝑑 ), while 𝕃𝑒𝑐,𝒫 (ℱ𝑑 ) is the space obtained when starting from UC𝑏 (Ω𝑑 ) instead of 𝐢𝑏 (Ω𝑑 ). extension

We denote by

Proposition 5.5. Let 𝔼0 (β‹…) = sup𝑃 βˆˆπ’« 𝐸 𝑃 [ β‹… ]. Then strictly monotone for each of the cases (i) ℋ𝑑 = 𝐢𝑏 (Ω𝑑 ), (ii) ℋ𝑑 = UC𝑏 (Ω𝑑 ), ∘ (iii) ℋ𝑑 = π•ƒβˆž 𝑐,𝒫 (ℱ𝑑 ), ∘ (iv) ℋ𝑑 = π•ƒβˆž 𝑒𝑐,𝒫 (ℱ𝑑 ).

𝔼0

is (ℋ𝑑 )-locally

Together with Corollary 5.4, this yields a uniqueness result for extensions. Before giving the proof, we indicate some examples covered by this result;

(𝔼𝑑 ) is β„‹ = 𝕃1𝑒𝑐,𝒫 in both cases. (This 1 1 that 𝕃𝑒𝑐,𝒫 = 𝕃𝑐,𝒫 when 𝒫 is tight; cf. the

see also Example 2.1. The domain of statement implicitly uses the fact proof of [23, Proposition 5.2].)

27

(a) Let

(𝔼𝑑 )

be the

lary 5.4 applies: if

ˆ𝑇 ) βŠ† β„‹ ˆ𝑑 𝔼𝑑 (β„‹

ˆ𝑑 β„‹

𝐺-expectation

as introduced in [27, 28]. Then Corol-

is any of the spaces in (i)(iv), the invariance property

ˆ𝑇 β„‹

is satised and

is dense in

β„‹.

(b) Using the construction given in [23], the

𝐺-expectation

can be ex-

tended to the case when there is no nite upper bound for the volatility. This

𝐺 (and then 𝒫 need not be tight). Λ† 𝑑 = UC𝑏 (Ω𝑑 ) since 𝔼𝑑 (β„‹ ˆ𝑇 ) βŠ† β„‹ Λ† 𝑑 is satised β„‹ ∞ ∘ [23, Corollary 3.6], or also with ℋ𝑑 = 𝕃𝑒𝑐,𝒫 (ℱ𝑑 ).

corresponds to a possibly innite function Here Corollary 5.4 applies with by the remark stated after

Proof of Proposition 5.5.

𝑑 ∈ [0, 𝑇 ]. All topological notions in this proof β€² β€² are expressed with respect to 𝑑(πœ”, πœ” ) := βˆ₯πœ” βˆ’ πœ” βˆ₯𝑑 . Let 𝑋, π‘Œ ∈ ℋ𝑑 be such that 𝑋 β‰₯ π‘Œ 𝒫 -q.s. and π‘ƒβˆ— (𝑋 > π‘Œ ) > 0 for some π‘ƒβˆ— ∈ 𝒫 . By translating and multiplying with positive constants, we may assume that 1 β‰₯ 𝑋 β‰₯ π‘Œ β‰₯ 0. Fix

We prove the cases (i)(iv) separately. (i) Choose

𝛿>0

small enough so that

𝐴1 := {𝑋 β‰₯ π‘Œ + 2𝛿}, Then

𝐴1

and

𝐴2

𝐴1 .

0≀𝑓 ≀1

(5.1)

as well as

𝑓 =0

on

𝐴2

and

It remains to check that

𝔼0 (𝑋𝑓 ) > 𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 ), If

𝐴2 := {𝑋 ≀ π‘Œ + 𝛿}.

𝑑(πœ”, 𝐴2 ) 𝑑(πœ”, 𝐴1 ) + 𝑑(πœ”, 𝐴2 )

is a continuous function satisfying on

and let

are disjoint closed sets and

𝑓 (πœ”) :=

𝑓 =1

π‘ƒβˆ— {𝑋 β‰₯ π‘Œ + 2𝛿} > 0

𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 ) = 0,

sup 𝐸 𝑃 [𝑋𝑓 ] > sup 𝐸 𝑃 [π‘Œ 𝑓 ].

i.e.,

𝑃 βˆˆπ’«

the observation that

𝑃 βˆˆπ’«

𝔼0 (𝑋𝑓 ) β‰₯ 𝐸 π‘ƒβˆ— [𝑋𝑓 ] β‰₯ 2π›Ώπ‘ƒβˆ— (𝐴1 ) > 0

already yields the proof.

𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 ) > 0. For πœ€ > 0, let π‘ƒπœ€ ∈ 𝒫 be 𝑓 ] β‰₯ 𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 ) βˆ’ πœ€. Since 𝑋 > π‘Œ + 𝛿 on {𝑓 > 0} and since have 𝑋𝑓 β‰₯ (π‘Œ + 𝛿)𝑓 β‰₯ (π‘Œ + π›Ώπ‘Œ )𝑓 and therefore

Hence, we may assume that

𝑃 such that 𝐸 πœ€ [π‘Œ

0 ≀ π‘Œ ≀ 1,

we

𝔼0 (𝑋𝑓 ) β‰₯ lim sup 𝐸 π‘ƒπœ€ [(π‘Œ + π›Ώπ‘Œ )𝑓 ] πœ€β†’0

= lim sup (1 + 𝛿)𝐸 π‘ƒπœ€ [π‘Œ 𝑓 ] πœ€β†’0

= (1 + 𝛿) 𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 ). As

𝛿>0

and

𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 ) > 0,

this ends the proof of (i).

(ii) The proof for this case is the same; we merely have to check that the function

𝑓

𝑍 := 𝑋 βˆ’ π‘Œ is π‘Œ are. Thus there exists πœ€ > 0 such that 𝑑(πœ”, πœ” β€² ) ≀ πœ€. We observe that 𝑑(𝐴1 , 𝐴2 ) β‰₯ πœ€

dened in (5.1) is uniformly continuous. Indeed,

uniformly continuous since

βˆ£π‘(πœ”) βˆ’ 𝑍(πœ” β€² )∣ < 𝛿

𝑋

whenever

and

and hence that the denominator in (5.1) is bounded away from zero. One then checks by direct calculation that

𝑓

28

is Lipschitz continuous.

(iii) We recall that

∘ π•ƒβˆž 𝒫 (ℱ𝑑 )

coincides with the set of bounded

𝒫 -quasi

continuous functions (up to modication); cf. [10, Theorem 25]. That is, a bounded

β„±π‘‘βˆ˜ -measurable

function

β„Ž

∘ π•ƒβˆž 𝒫 (ℱ𝑑 ) if and only if for all πœ€ > 0 that 𝑃 (Ξ›) > 1 βˆ’ πœ€ for all 𝑃 ∈ 𝒫 and

is in

Ξ› βŠ† Ξ© such β„Žβˆ£Ξ› is continuous. For 𝛿 > 0 small enough, we have π‘ƒβˆ— ({𝑋 β‰₯ π‘Œ + 2𝛿}) > 0. Then, we nd a closed set Ξ› βŠ† Ξ© such that 𝑋 and π‘Œ are continuous on Ξ› and there exists a closed set

such that the restriction

(1 + 𝛿) 𝔼0 (1Λ𝑐 ) < 𝛿 2 𝔼0 (1{𝑋β‰₯π‘Œ +2𝛿}βˆ©Ξ› ).

can

(5.2)

Dene the disjoint closed sets

𝐴1 := {𝑋 β‰₯ π‘Œ + 2𝛿} ∩ Ξ›, and let

𝑓

𝐴2 := {𝑋 ≀ π‘Œ + 𝛿} ∩ Ξ›,

be the continuous function (5.1). We distinguish two cases. Sup-

pose rst that

𝛿𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 ) ≀ (1 + 𝛿) 𝔼0 (1Λ𝑐 );

then, using (5.2),

𝔼0 (𝑋𝑓 ) β‰₯ 2𝛿𝔼0 (1𝐴1 ) > (1 + 𝛿)𝛿 βˆ’1 𝔼0 (1Λ𝑐 ) β‰₯ 𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 ) and we are done. Otherwise, we have

𝛿𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 ) > (1 + 𝛿) 𝔼0 (1Λ𝑐 ).

Moreover,

𝔼0 (𝑋𝑓 1Ξ› ) β‰₯ (1 + 𝛿)𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 1Ξ› ) can be shown as in (i); we simply replace 𝑓 𝑓 1Ξ› in that argument. Using the subadditivity of 𝔼0 , we deduce that

by

𝔼0 (𝑋𝑓 ) + (1 + 𝛿) 𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 1Λ𝑐 ) β‰₯ 𝔼0 (𝑋𝑓 1Ξ› ) + (1 + 𝛿) 𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 1Λ𝑐 ) β‰₯ (1 + 𝛿) 𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 1Ξ› ) + (1 + 𝛿) 𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 1Λ𝑐 ) β‰₯ (1 + 𝛿) 𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 ) and hence

𝔼0 (𝑋𝑓 )βˆ’π”Ό0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 ) β‰₯ 𝛿𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 )βˆ’(1+𝛿) 𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 1Λ𝑐 ) β‰₯ 𝛿𝔼0 (π‘Œ 𝑓 )βˆ’(1+𝛿) 𝔼0 (1Λ𝑐 ). The right hand side is strictly positive by assumption. (iv) The proof is similar to the one for (iii): we use [23, Proposition 5.2] instead of [10, Theorem 25] to nd

Ξ›,

and then the observation made in the

proof of (ii) shows that the resulting function

𝑓

is uniformly continuous.

References [1] P. Artzner, F. Delbaen, J.-M. Eber, and D. Heath. Coherent measures of risk. Math. Finance, 9(3):203228, 1999. [2] M. Avellaneda, A. Levy, and A. ParΓ‘s. Pricing and hedging derivative securities in markets with uncertain volatilities. Appl. Math. Finance, 2(2):7388, 1995. [3] K. Bichteler. Stochastic integration and 𝐿𝑝 -theory of semimartingales. Ann. Probab., 9(1):4989, 1981.

29

[4] J. Bion-Nadal and M. Kervarec. Dynamic risk measuring under model uncertainty: taking advantage of the hidden probability measure. Preprint arXiv:1012.5850v1. [5] J. Bion-Nadal and M. Kervarec. Risk measuring under model uncertainty. To

appear in Ann. Appl. Probab.

[6] P. Cheridito, H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and N. Victoir. Second-order backward stochastic dierential equations and fully nonlinear parabolic PDEs. Comm. Pure Appl. Math., 60(7):10811110, 2007. [7] F. Delbaen. The structure of m-stable sets and in particular of the set of risk neutral measures. In SΓ©minaire de ProbabilitΓ©s XXXIX, volume 1874 of Lecture Notes in Math., pages 215258, Springer, Berlin, 2006. [8] F. Delbaen and W. Schachermayer. The Mathematics of Arbitrage. Springer, Berlin, 2006. [9] C. Dellacherie and P. A. Meyer. Probabilities and Potential B. North Holland, Amsterdam, 1982. [10] L. Denis, M. Hu, and S. Peng. Function spaces and capacity related to a sublinear expectation: application to 𝐺-Brownian motion paths. Potential Anal., 34(2):139161, 2011. [11] L. Denis and C. Martini. A theoretical framework for the pricing of contingent claims in the presence of model uncertainty. Ann. Appl. Probab., 16(2):827 852, 2006. [12] N. El Karoui. Les aspects probabilistes du contrΓ΄le stochastique. In Ecole d'Γ©tΓ© de probabilitΓ©es de Saint-Flour, volume 876 of Lecture Notes in Math., pages 73238, Springer, Berlin, 1981. [13] D. Fernholz and I. Karatzas. Optimal arbitrage under model uncertainty. Ann. Appl. Probab., 21(6):21912225, 2011. [14] H. FΓΆllmer and A. Schied. Robust preferences and convex measures of risk. In Advances in Finance and Stochastics, pages 3956, Springer, Berlin, 2002. [15] H. FΓΆllmer and A. Schied. Stochastic Finance: An Introduction in Discrete Time. W. de Gruyter, Berlin, 2nd edition, 2004. [16] Y. Hu and S. Peng. Some estimates for martingale representation under 𝐺expectation. Preprint arXiv:1004.1098v1, 2010. [17] J. Jacod and M. Yor. Γ‰tude des solutions extrΓ©males et reprΓ©sentation intΓ©grale des solutions pour certains problΓ¨mes de martingales. Z. Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie und Verw. Gebiete, 38(2):83125, 1977. [18] R. L. Karandikar. On pathwise stochastic integration. Stochastic Process. Appl., 57(1):1118, 1995. [19] N. El Karoui and M.-C. Quenez. Dynamic programming and pricing of contingent claims in an incomplete market. SIAM J. Control Optim., 33(1):2966, 1995. [20] X. Li and S. Peng. Stopping times and related ItΓ΄'s calculus with 𝐺-Brownian motion. Stochastic Process. Appl., 121(7):14921508, 2011. [21] T. J. Lyons. Uncertain volatility and the risk-free synthesis of derivatives. Appl. Math. Finance, 2(2):117133, 1995. [22] J. Neveu. Discrete-Parameter Martingales. North-Holland, Amsterdam, 1975. [23] M. Nutz. Random 𝐺-expectations. Preprint arXiv:1009.2168v1, 2010.

30

[24] M. Nutz. A quasi-sure approach to the control of non-Markovian stochastic dierential equations. Electron. J. Probab., 17(23):123, 2012. [25] M. Nutz. Pathwise construction of stochastic integrals. Preprint arXiv:1108.2981v1, 2011. [26] S. Peng. Nonlinear expectations and nonlinear Markov chains. Chinese Ann. Math. Ser. B, 26(2):159184, 2005. [27] S. Peng. 𝐺-expectation, 𝐺-Brownian motion and related stochastic calculus of Itô type. In Stochastic Analysis and Applications, volume 2 of Abel Symp., pages 541567, Springer, Berlin, 2007. [28] S. Peng. Multi-dimensional 𝐺-Brownian motion and related stochastic calculus under 𝐺-expectation. Stochastic Process. Appl., 118(12):22232253, 2008. [29] S. Peng. Backward stochastic dierential equation, nonlinear expectation and their applications. In R. Bhatia, editor, Proceedings of the International Congress of Mathematicians 2010, Hyderabad, India, volume 1, pages 393432, World Scientic, Singapore, 2011. [30] S. Peng. Nonlinear expectations and stochastic calculus under uncertainty. Preprint arXiv:1002.4546v1, 2010. [31] H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and J. Zhang. Quasi-sure stochastic analysis through aggregation. Electron. J. Probab., 16:18441879, 2011. [32] H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and J. Zhang. Wellposedness of second order backward SDEs. To appear in Probab. Theory Related Fields. [33] H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and J. Zhang. Dual formulation of second order target problems. To appear in Ann. Appl. Probab., 2010. [34] H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and J. Zhang. Martingale representation theorem for the 𝐺-expectation. Stochastic Process. Appl., 121(2):265287, 2011. [35] Y. Song. Some properties on 𝐺-evaluation and its applications to 𝐺-martingale decomposition. Sci. China Math., 54(2):287300, 2011. [36] D. Stroock and S. R. S. Varadhan. Multidimensional Diusion Processes. Springer, New York, 1979. [37] J. Xu and B. Zhang. Martingale characterization of 𝐺-Brownian motion. Stochastic Process. Appl., 119(1):232248, 2009.

31