Superhedging and Dynamic Risk Measures under Volatility Uncertainty Marcel Nutz
β
β
H. Mete Soner
First version: November 12, 2010. This version: June 2, 2012.
Abstract We consider dynamic sublinear expectations (i.e., time-consistent coherent risk measures) whose scenario sets consist of singular measures corresponding to a general form of volatility uncertainty. We derive a cΓ dlΓ g nonlinear martingale which is also the value process of a superhedging problem. The superhedging strategy is obtained from a representation similar to the optional decomposition. Furthermore, we prove an optional sampling theorem for the nonlinear martingale and characterize it as the solution of a second order backward SDE. The uniqueness of dynamic extensions of static sublinear expectations is also studied.
Keywords volatility uncertainty, risk measure, time consistency, nonlinear martin-
gale, superhedging, replication, second order BSDE, πΊ-expectation AMS 2000 Subject Classications primary 91B30, 93E20, 60G44; secondary 60H30 JEL Classications D81, G11.
Acknowledgements
Research supported by the European Research Council
Grant 228053-FiRM, the Swiss National Science Foundation Grant PDFM2120424/1 and the ETH Foundation.
The authors thank two anonymous
referees for helpful comments.
1
Introduction
Coherent risk measures were introduced in [1] as a way to quantify the risk associated with a nancial position. Since then, coherent risk measures and sublinear expectations (which are the same up to the sign convention) have been studied by numerous authors; see [15, 29, 30] for extensive references. β β
Department of Mathematics, Columbia University,
[email protected] Department
and
of
Mathematics,
ETH
Zurich,
[email protected] 1
Swiss
Finance
Institute,
Most of these works consider the case where scenarios are probability measures absolutely continuous with respect to a given reference probability (important early exceptions are [14, 26]). The present paper studies dynamic sublinear expectations and superhedging under volatility uncertainty, which is naturally related to singular measures.
The concept of volatility uncer-
tainty was introduced in nancial mathematics by [2, 11, 21] and has recently
πΊ-expectations
received considerable attention due to its relation to
[27, 28]
and second order backward stochastic dierential equations [6, 32], called 2BSDEs for brevity. Any (static) sublinear expectation
β°0β ,
dened on the set of bounded
measurable functions on a measurable space
(Ξ©, β±),
has a convex-dual rep-
resentation
β°0β (π) = sup πΈ π [π]
(1.1)
π βπ«
π«
for a certain set
of measures which are
π -additive
certain continuity properties (cf. [15, Section 4]).
as soon as
β°0β
satises
π«
The elements of
can
be seen as possible scenarios in the presence of uncertainty and hence (1.1) corresponds to the worst-case expectation. In this paper, we take the canonical space of continuous paths and
π«
Ξ©
to be
to be a set of martingale laws
for the canonical process, corresponding to dierent scenarios of volatilities. For this case,
π«
is typically not dominated by a nite measure and (1.1)
was studied in [5, 10, 11] by capacity-theoretic methods. We remark that from the pricing point of view, the restriction to the martingale case entails no loss of generality in an arbitrage-free setting. An example with arbitrage was studied in [13]. While any set of martingale laws gives rise to a static sublinear expectation via (1.1), we are interested in
dynamic
sublinear expectations; i.e.,
conditional versions of (1.1) satisfying a time-consistency property. If dominated by a probability
πβ ,
π«
is
a natural extension of (1.1) is given by β²
β°π‘β,πβ (π) = ess supπβ πΈ π [πβ£β±π‘β ] πβ -a.s., π β² βπ«(β±π‘β ,πβ )
where
π«(β±π‘β , πβ ) = {π β² β π« : π β² = πβ
on
ltration generated by the canonical process.
β±π‘β }
π«
(see [7]).
π½β = {β±π‘β }
is the
Such dynamic expectations
are well-studied; in particular, time consistency of by a stability property of
and
β° β,πβ
can be characterized
In the non-dominated case, we can
similarly consider the family of random variables
{β°π‘β,π (π), π β π«}.
Since
a reference measure is lacking, it is not straightforward to construct a single random variable
β°π‘β (π)
such that β²
β°π‘β (π) = β°π‘β,π (π) := ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±π‘β ] π -a.s.
for all
π β π«.
(1.2)
π β² βπ«(β±π‘β ,π )
This problem of aggregation has been solved in several examples. ticular, the
πΊ-expectations
and random
2
πΊ-expectations
In par-
[23] (recalled in
Section 2) correspond to special cases of (1.2).
The construction of
πΊ-
expectations is based on a PDE, which directly yields random variables dened for all
π β Ξ©.
The random
πΊ-expectations
are dened pathwise
using regular conditional probability distributions. A general study of aggregation problems is presented in [31]; see also [4]. However, the study of aggregation is not an object of the present paper.
In view of the diverse
approaches, we shall proceed axiomatically and start with a given aggregated family
{β°π‘β (π), π‘ β [0, π ]}.
πΊ-expectations,
Having in mind the example of (random)
this family is assumed to be given in the raw ltration
π½β
and without any regularity in the time variable. The main goal of the present paper is to provide basic technology for the study of dynamic sublinear expectations under volatility uncertainty as
{β°π‘β (π), π‘ β [0, π ]}, we construct a corresponding cΓ dlΓ g process β°(π), called the β° -martingale associated with π , in a suitably enlarged ltration π½ (Proposition 4.5). We use this
stochastic processes.
Given the family
process to dene the sublinear expectation at stopping times and prove an
β° -martingales (Theorem 4.10). Furthermore, β°(π) into an integral of the canonical process
optional sampling theorem for we obtain a decomposition of
and an increasing process (Proposition 4.11), similarly as in the classical op-
β° -martingale yields the dynamic π yields the superhedging price of the nancial claim π and the integrand π superhedging strategy. We also provide a connection between β° -martingales π and 2BSDEs by characterizing (β°(π), π ) as the minimal solution of such a tional decomposition [19]. In particular, the
backward equation (Theorem 4.16). Our last result concerns the uniqueness of time-consistent extensions and gives conditions under which (1.2) is indeed the only possible extension of the static expectation (1.1). In particular, we introduce the notion of local strict monotonicity to deal with the singularity of the measures (Proposition 5.3). To obtain our results, we rely on methods from stochastic optimal control and the general theory of stochastic processes. Indeed, from the point of view of dynamic programming,
β°π‘β (π)
is the value process of a control
problem dened over a set of measures, and time consistency corresponds to Bellman's principle. Taking the control representation (1.2) as our starting point allows us to consider the measures
π β π«
separately in many
arguments and therefore to apply standard arguments of the general theory. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows.
In Section 2 we
detail the setting and notation. Section 3 relates time consistency to a pasting property.
In Section 4 we construct the
β° -martingale
and provide the
optional sampling theorem, the decomposition, and the characterization by a 2BSDE. Section 5 studies the uniqueness of time-consistent extensions.
3
2
Preliminaries
We x a constant
π >0
Ξ© = {π β πΆ([0, π ]; Rπ ) : π0 = 0}
and let
be the
canonical space of continuous paths equipped with the uniform topology. We
π΅ the canonical process π΅π‘ (π) = ππ‘ , by π0 the Wiener measure π½β = {β±π‘β }0β€π‘β€π , β±π‘β = π(π΅π , π β€ π‘) the raw ltration generated
denote by and by by
π΅.
As in [10, 23, 33, 32] we shall use the so-called strong formulation of
volatility uncertainty in this paper; i.e., we consider martingale laws induced by stochastic integrals of
π΅
under
π0 .
More precisely, we dene
π«π
to be
the set of laws
π πΌ := π0 β (π πΌ )β1 ,
ππ‘πΌ :=
where
(π0β«) π‘
πΌπ 1/2 ππ΅π ,
π‘ β [0, π ]
(2.1)
0 and
πΌ
π½β -progressively measurable processes with values πΓπ denotes the set β£πΌπ‘ β£ ππ‘ < β π0 -a.s. Here π>0 π β β
ranges over all
π>0 π satisfying
β«π 0
in of
strictly positive denite matrices and the stochastic integral in (2.1) is the ItΓ΄ integral under
π0 ,
constructed in
coincides with the set denoted by
π½β
π«π
(cf. [36, p. 97]). We remark that
π«π
in [31].
π« β π«π which represents π‘ β [0, π ], we dene πΏ1π« (β±π‘β ) to variables π satisfying
The basic object in this paper is a nonempty set the possible scenarios for the volatility. For be the space of
β±π‘β -measurable
random
β₯πβ₯πΏ1 := sup β₯πβ₯πΏ1 (π ) < β, π«
π βπ«
β₯πβ₯πΏ1 (π ) := πΈ[β£πβ£]. More precisely, we take equivalences classes with π« -quasi-sure equality so that πΏ1π« (β±π‘β ) becomes a Banach space. (Two functions are equal π« -quasi-surely, π« -q.s. for short, if they are equal up to a π« -polar set. A set is called π« -polar if it is a π -nullset for all π β π« .) 1 1 β We also x a nonempty subset β of πΏπ« := πΏπ« (β±π ) whose elements play the role of nancial claims. We emphasize that in applications, β is typically 1 smaller than πΏπ« . The following is a motivating example for many of the where
respect to
considerations in this paper.
Example 2.1. πΊ-expectation
(i) Given real numbers
(for dimension
π = 1)
0 β€ π β€ π < β,
corresponds to the choice
} π« = π πΌ β π«π : π β€ πΌ β€ π π0 Γ ππ‘-a.e. , {
cf. [10, Section 3]. Here the symbol
πΊ(πΎ) := If
π = π (π΅π )
the associated
πΊ
(2.2)
refers to the function
1 sup ππΎ. 2 πβ€πβ€π π , then β°π‘β,πΊ (π) is dened equation ββπ‘ π’ β πΊ(π’π₯π₯ ) = 0 with
for a suciently regular function
via the solution of the nonlinear heat
4
π’β£π‘=π = π . In [27], the mapping β°π‘β,πΊ is extended to random variables of the form π = π (π΅π‘1 , . . . , π΅π‘π ) by a stepwise evaluation of the PDE and nally to the β₯ β
β₯πΏ1 -completion β of the set of all such π« random variables. For π β β, the πΊ-expectation then satises boundary condition
β²
β°π‘β,πΊ (π) = ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±π‘β ] π -a.s.
for all
π β π«,
π β² βπ«(β±π‘β ,π )
β coincides with the β₯β
β₯πΏ1 -completion π« πΆπ (Ξ©), the set of bounded continuous functions on Ξ©, and is strictly smaller 1 than πΏπ« as soon as π β= π. (ii) The random πΊ-expectation corresponds to the case where π, π are
which is of the form (1.2). The space of
random processes instead of constants and is directly constructed from a set
π«
of measures (cf. [23]). In this case the space
of
UCπ (Ξ©),
β
β₯ β
β₯πΏ1 -completion π« functions on Ξ©. If π is
is the
the set of bounded uniformly continuous
nite-valued and uniformly bounded,
3
β
coincides with the space from (i).
Time Consistency and Pasting
π« β π«π β β πΏ1π« is xed π½β -stopping times
In this section, we consider time consistency as a property of the set and obtain some auxiliary results for later use. throughout.
Moreover, we let
π― (π½β )
The set
be the set of all
taking nitely many values; this choice is motivated by the applications in the subsequent section. However, the results of this section hold true also if
π― (π½β )
is replaced by an arbitrary set of
π½β -stopping
times containing
π β‘ 0;
in particular, the set of all stopping times and the set of all deterministic times. Given
π β β±πβ
and
π β π«,
we use the standard notation
π«(π, π ) = {π β² β π« : π β² = π
on
π}.
At the level of measures, time consistency can then be dened as follows.
Denition 3.1. ess supπ πΈ π π β² βπ«(β±πβ ,π )
β²
[
The set
ess supπ
π« β²
π β²β² βπ«(β±πβ ,π β² )
π½β -time-consistent on β if ] β²β² β² πΈ π [πβ£β±πβ ] β±πβ = ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±πβ ] π -a.s. β² β is
π βπ«(β±π ,π )
(3.1) for all
π β π«, π β β
and
πβ€π
in
π― (π½β ).
This property embodies the principle of dynamic programming (e.g., [12]). We shall relate it to the following notion of stability, also called mstability, fork-convexity, stability under concatenation, etc.
Denition 3.2. π βπ―
(π½β ),
π« is stable under π½β -pasting if for all π β π« , Ξβ π1 , π2 β π«(β±πβ , π ), the measure πΒ― dened by [ ] πΒ― (π΄) := πΈ π π1 (π΄β£β±πβ )1Ξ + π2 (π΄β£β±πβ )1Ξπ , π΄ β β±πβ (3.2) The set
β±πβ and
is again an element of
π«. 5
As
π½β
is the only ltration considered in this section, we shall sometimes
β
omit the qualier π½ .
Lemma 3.3. The set π«π is stable under pasting. Proof.
π, π1 , π2 , π, Ξ, πΒ― be as in Denition 3.2. Using the notation (2.1), π πΌ πΌπ = π for π = 1, 2. Setting let πΌ, πΌ be such that π = π and π π Let
πΌ Β― π’ (π) := [ ] 1[[0,π (π πΌ )]] (π’)πΌπ’ (π) + 1]]π (π πΌ ),π ]] (π’) πΌπ’1 (π)1Ξ (π πΌ (π)) + πΌπ’2 (π)1Ξπ (π πΌ (π)) , we have
πΒ― = π πΌΒ― β π«π
by the arguments in [33, Appendix].
The previous proof also shows that the set appearing in (2.2) is stable under pasting. The following result is classical.
Lemma 3.4. Let π β π― (π½β ), π β πΏ1π« and π β π« . If π« is stable under pasting, then there exists a sequence ππ β π«(β±πβ , π ) such that β²
ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±πβ ] = lim πΈ ππ [πβ£β±πβ ] πββ
π β² βπ«(β±πβ ,π )
π -a.s.,
where the limit is increasing π -a.s. Proof.
a.s. upward ltering (cf. [22,
β²
{πΈ π [πβ£β±πβ ] : π β² β π«(β±πβ , π )} is π β Proposition VI-1-1]). Given π1 , π2 β π«(β±π , π ),
It suces to show that the family
we set
and dene and
πΒ― β π«
{ } Ξ := πΈ π1 [πβ£β±πβ ] > πΈ π2 [πβ£β±πβ ] β β±πβ [ ] πΒ― (π΄) := πΈ π π1 (π΄β£β±πβ )1Ξ + π2 (π΄β£β±πβ )1Ξπ . Then πΒ― = π
on
β±πβ
by the stability. Moreover,
Β―
πΈ π [πβ£β±πβ ] = πΈ π1 [πβ£β±πβ ] β¨ πΈ π2 [πβ£β±πβ ] π -a.s., showing that the family is upward ltering. To relate time consistency to stability under pasting, we introduce the following closedness property.
Denition 3.5. π β π«π If
π«
π« is maximally chosen for β β² πΈ π [π] β€ supπ β² βπ« πΈ π [π] for all π β β.
We say that
satisfying
is dominated by a reference probability
with a subset of
πΏ1 (πβ )
πβ ,
then
π«
if
π«
contains all
can be identied
by the Radon-Nikodym theorem.
If furthermore
β = πΏβ (πβ ), the Hahn-Banach theorem implies that π« is maximally chosen 1 if and only if π« is convex and closed for weak topology of πΏ (πβ ). Along these lines, the following result can be seen as a generalization of [7, Theorem 12]; in fact, we merely replace functional-analytic arguments by algebraic ones.
6
Proposition 3.6. With respect to the ltration π½β , we have: (i) If π« is stable under pasting, then π« is time-consistent on πΏ1π« . (ii) If π« is time-consistent on β and maximally chosen for β, then π« is stable under pasting. Proof. (i) This implication is standard; we provide the argument for later
π β²β² := π β² on arbitrary π β π«
reference. The inequality β₯ in (3.1) follows by considering the left hand side. To see the converse inequality, x an and choose a sequence
ππ β π«(β±πβ , π ) β π«(β±πβ , π )
as in Lemma 3.4. Then
monotone convergence yields
πΈ
π
[
π
ess sup
πΈ
π β² βπ«(β±πβ ,π )
πβ²
[πβ£β±πβ ] β±πβ
]
= lim πΈ ππ [πβ£β±πβ ] πββ
β²
β€ ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±πβ ] π -a.s. π β² βπ«(β±πβ ,π )
π«
(ii) Let
be time-consistent and let
tion 3.2. For any
π β β,
π, π1 , π2 , π, Ξ, πΒ―
be as in Deni-
we have
[ ] Β― πΈ π [π] = πΈ π πΈ π1 [πβ£β±πβ ]1Ξ + πΈ π2 [πβ£β±πβ ]1Ξπ [ ] π π π β²β² β β€πΈ ess sup πΈ [πβ£β±π ] π β²β² βπ«(β±πβ ,π )
β€ sup πΈ π
β²
[
π β² βπ«
ess supπ
β²
π β²β² βπ«(β±πβ ,π β² )
] β²β² πΈ π [πβ£β±πβ ]
β²
= sup πΈ π [π], π β² βπ« where the last equality uses (3.1) with and
4
πΒ― β π«π
π β‘ 0.
by Lemma 3.3, we conclude that
Since π« Β― π β π«.
is maximally chosen
β° -Martingales
As discussed in the introduction, our starting point in this section is a given
{β°π‘β (π), π‘ β [0, π ]} of random variables which will serve as a raw version of the β° -martingale to be constructed. We recall that the sets π« β π«π 1 and β β πΏπ« are xed. family
Assumption 4.1.
Throughout Section 4, we assume that
π β β and π‘ β [0, π ], β variable β°π‘ (π) such that
(i) for all
there exists an
β²
β°π‘β (π) = ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±π‘β ] π -a.s. π β² βπ«(β±π‘β ,π )
(ii) the set
π«
is stable under
π½β -pasting.
7
β±π‘β -measurable for all
π β π«.
random
(4.1)
The rst assumption was discussed in the introduction; cf. (1.2). With the motivating Example 2.1 in mind, we ask for (4.1) to hold at deterministic times rather than at stopping times. The second assumption is clearly motivated by Proposition 3.6(ii), and Proposition 3.6(i) shows that
π«
is
time-consistent in the sense of Denition 3.1. (We could assume the latter property directly, but stability under pasting is more suitable for applications.) In particular, we have β²
β°π β (π) = ess supπ πΈ π [β°π‘β (π)β£β±π β ] π -a.s.
for all
π β π«,
(4.2)
π β² βπ«(β±π β ,π )
0 β€ π β€ π‘ β€ π and π β β. If we assume that β°π‘β (π) is again an element β of the domain β, this amounts to {β°π‘ } being time-consistent (at determinβ β β istic times) in the sense that the semigroup property β°π β β°π‘ = β°π is satisβ ed. However, β°π‘ (π) need not be in β in general; e.g., for certain random πΊ-expectations. Inspired by the theory of viscosity solutions, we introduce the following extended notion of time consistency, which is clearly implied by (4.2).
Denition 4.2. A family (πΌπ‘ )0β€π‘β€π of mappings πΌπ‘ : β β πΏ1π« (β±π‘β ) is called π½β -time-consistent at deterministic times if for all 0 β€ π β€ π‘ β€ π and π β β, πΌπ (π) β€ (β₯) πΌπ (π)
for all
π β πΏ1π« (β±π‘β ) β© β
such that
πΌπ‘ (π) β€ (β₯) π.
One can give a similar denition for stopping times taking countably many values. (Note that stopping time
πΌπ (π)
is not necessarily well dened for a general
π .)
Remark 4.3. If Assumption 4.1 is weakened by requiring π« to be stable only under
π½β -pastings at deterministic times (i.e., Denition 3.1 holds with π― (π½β )
replaced by the set of deterministic times), then all results in this section remain true with the same proofs, except for Theorem 4.10, Lemma 4.15 and the last statement in Theorem 4.16.
4.1
Construction of the
β° -Martingale
Our rst task is to turn the collection
{β°π‘β (π), π‘ β [0, π ]} of random variables
into a reasonable stochastic process. As usual, this requires an extension of the ltration. We denote by
π½+ = {β±π‘+ }0β€π‘β€π ,
β β±π‘+ := β±π‘+
the minimal right continuous ltration containing
β and β±π +
0β€π‘π‘ β±π π« π© of
β©
π½+ by the collection
to obtain the ltration
F = {β±π‘ }0β€π‘β€π ,
β := β±π‘+
Then
F is right continuous and a natural analogue of the usual augmen-
tation that is standard in the case where a reference probability is given. More precisely, if
π«
is dominated by some probability measure, then one
can nd a minimal dominating measure a
πβ -nullset)
mark that
and then
πβ
(such that every
π« -polar
F is in general strictly smaller than the π« -universal augmentation
βπ π βπ« π½ , which seems to be too large for our purposes. Here β the π -augmentation of π½ .
β©
Since
set is
F coincides with the πβ -augmentation of π½+ . We re-
π½
and
F+
π½β
π
denotes
π« -polar sets, they can be identied for + β that β±π = β±π = β±π π« -q.s. We also recall
dier only by
most purposes; note in particular
the following result (e.g., [17, Theorem 1.5], [31, Lemma 8.2]), which shows that
F and π½β dier only by π -nullsets for each π β π« .
Lemma 4.4. Let π β π« . Then π½β π is right continuous and in particular contains F. Moreover, (π, π΅) has the predictable representation property; i.e., for any right continuous (π½β π , π )-local martingale π there exists an β« π π½β -predictable process π such that π = π0 + (π ) π ππ΅ , π -a.s. Proof.
We sketch the argument for the convenience of the reader. We dene
π Λπ‘ = πβ¨π΅β©π‘ /ππ‘ taking values in π>0 π π Γ ππ‘-a.e., note β1/2 that (Λ π) β« is square-integrable for π΅ by its very denition, and consider π‘ ππ’ )β1/2 ππ΅π’ . Let π½π be the raw ltration generated by π . Since ππ‘ := (π ) 0 (Λ a predictable process
π is a π -Brownian motion by LΓ©vy's characterization, the π -augmentation π π½π is right continuous and π has the representation property. Moreover, π π π as π β π«π , [31, Lemma 8.1] yields that π½π = π½β . Thus π½β is also right continuous and π΅ has the representation property since any integral of π is also an integral of π΅ . We deduce from Lemma 4.4 that for is a (local) cess
π΅.
π« -polar
(F, π )-martingale.
In particular, this applies to the canonical pro-
Note that Lemma 4.4 does not imply that
F and π½β coincide up to
sets. E.g., consider the set
π΄ :=
{
} β lim sup π‘β1 β¨π΅β©π‘ = lim inf π‘β1 β¨π΅β©π‘ = 1 β β±0+ . π‘β0
π‘β0
Then the lemma asserts that number is the same for all for
π β π« , any (local) (π½β , π )-martingale
π.
(4.3)
π (π΄) β {0, 1} for all π β π« , but not that this πΌ πΌ Indeed, π (π΄) = 1 for πΌ β‘ 1 but π (π΄) = 0
πΌ β‘ 2. We can now state the existence and uniqueness of the stochastic process
{β°π‘β (π), π‘ β [0, π ]}. For brevity, we shall say that π is an (F, π«)-supermartingale if π is an (F, π )-supermartingale for all π β π« ; derived from
analogous notation will be used in similar situations.
9
Proposition 4.5. Let π β β. There exists an F-optional process (ππ‘ )0β€π‘β€π such that all paths of π are cΓ dlΓ g and (i) π is the minimal (F, π«)-supermartingale with ππ = π ; i.e., if π is a cΓ dlΓ g (F, π«)-supermartingale with ππ = π , then π β₯ π up to a π« -polar set. β (π) := lim β (ii) ππ‘ = β°π‘+ πβπ‘ β°π (π) π« -q.s. for all 0 β€ π‘ < π , and ππ = π . (iii) π has the representation π -a.s.
β²
ππ‘ = ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±π‘ ] π β² βπ«(β±π‘ ,π )
for all π β π«.
(4.4)
Any of the properties (i),(ii),(iii) characterizes π uniquely up to π« -polar sets. The process π is denoted by β°(π) and called the (cΓ dlΓ g) β° -martingale associated with π . Proof.
We choose and x representatives for the classes
and dene the
ππ‘ (π) :=
β βͺ {Β±β}-valued lim sup
process
β°πβ (π)(π)
for
π
β°π‘β (π) β πΏ1π« (β±π‘β )
by
0β€π‘ π‘, moreover, π«(β± β , π ) = π«(β± , π ) since π«(β±π‘π , π ) β π«(β±π‘+ π π‘ π‘+ β and β± coincide up to π« -polar sets. In view of (4.6), the inequality β±π‘+ π‘
since
converse to (4.5) follows and (iii) is proved. To see the minimality property in (i), let with
ππ = π .
π
be an
β²
ππ‘ β₯ ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±π‘ ] π -a.s. π β² βπ«(β±
for all
π β π«.
π‘ ,π )
By (iii) the right hand side is all
(F, π«)-supermartingale
Exactly as in (4.5), we deduce that
π -a.s.
equal to
ππ‘ .
Hence
ππ‘ β₯ ππ‘ π« -q.s.
for
π β₯ π π« -q.s. when π is cΓ dlΓ g π and π β² are processes satisfying (i) or (ii) or (iii), then they π -modications of each other for all π β π« and thus coincide up to a
π‘
and
Finally, if are
π« -polar
set as soon as they are cΓ dlΓ g.
One can ask whether
β°(π)
is a
π« -modication
of
{β°π‘β (π), π‘ β [0, π ]};
i.e., whether
β°π‘ (π) = β°π‘β (π) π« -q.s.
for all
0 β€ π‘ β€ π.
β°(π) is a π« -modication as soon as there exists some π« -modication of the family {β°π‘β (π), π‘ β [0, π ]}, and this is the case π β only if π‘ 7β πΈ [β°π‘ (π)] is right continuous for all π β π« . We also
It is easy to see that cΓ dlΓ g if and
remark that Lemma 4.4 and the argument given for (4.5) yield
β°π‘ (π) β€ β°π‘β (π) π« -q.s.
for all
0β€π‘β€π
(4.7)
and so the question is only whether the converse inequality holds true as well. The answer is positive in several important cases; e.g., for the
11
πΊ-expectation
when
π
is suciently regular [35, Theorem 5.3] and the sublinear expec-
tation generated by a controlled stochastic dierential equation [24, Theorem 5.1]. The proof of the latter result yields a general technique to approach this problem in a given example. However, the following (admittedly degenerate) example shows that the answer is negative in a very general case; this reects the fact that the set than the set
π«(β±π‘β , π )
π«(β±π‘ , π )
in the representation (4.4) is smaller
in (4.1).
Example 4.6. We shall consider a πΊ-expectation dened on a set of irregular random variables.
β ) β = πΏ1π« (β±0+
Let
π = 1, π = 2
and let
π«
be as in (2.2).
We take
and dene
{ supπ βπ« πΈ π [π], π‘ = 0, β°π‘β (π) := π, 0 0. As noted after Lemma 3.3, the second part of Assumption 4.1 is also satised. Moreover, the cΓ dlΓ g β° -martingale is given by for
β°π‘ (π) = π,
π‘ β [0, π ].
π := 1π΄ , where π΄ is dened as in (4.3). Then β°0β (π) = 1 and β°0 (π) = 1π΄ are not equal π 2 -a.s. (i.e., the measure π πΌ for πΌ β‘ 2). In fact, 2 β there is no cΓ dlΓ g π« -modication since {β°π‘ (π)} coincides π -a.s. with the deterministic function π‘ 7β 1{0} (π‘).
Consider
We remark that the phenomenon appearing in the previous example is
π«
due to the presence of singular measures rather than the fact that
is
not dominated. In fact, one can give a similar example involving only two measures. Finally, let us mention that the situation is quite dierent if we assume that the given sublinear expectation is already placed in the larger ltration
π½
(i.e., Assumption 4.1 holds with
π½β
replaced by
π½),
which would be in line
with the paradigm of the usual assumptions in standard stochastic analysis. In this case, the arguments in the proof of Proposition 4.5 show that is always a
π« -modication.
This result is neat, but not very useful, since the
examples are typically constructed in
4.2
β°(π)
π½β .
Stopping Times
The direct construction of
πΊ-expectations
at stopping times is an unsolved
problem. Indeed, stopping times are typically fairly irregular functions and it is unclear how to deal with this in the existing constructions (see also [20]). On the other hand, we can easily evaluate the cΓ dlΓ g process stopping time tion at
π.
π
β°(π)
at a
and therefore dene the corresponding sublinear expecta-
In particular, this leads to a denition of
12
πΊ-expectations at general
stopping times. We show in this section that the resulting random variable
β°π (π)
indeed has the expected properties and that the time consistency ex-
tends to arbitrary
π½-stopping times; in other words, we prove an optional β° -martingales. Besides the obvious theoretical interest,
sampling theorem for the study of
β°(π)
at stopping times will allow us to verify integrability con-
ditions of the type class (D); cf. Lemma 4.15 below. We start by explaining the relations between the stopping times of the dierent ltrations.
Lemma 4.7. (i) Let π β π« and let π be an F-stopping time taking countably many values. Then there exists an π½β -stopping time π β (depending on π ) such that π = π β π -a.s. Moreover, for any such π β , the π-elds β±π and β±πββ dier only by π -nullsets. (ii) Let π be an F-stopping time. Then there exists an π½+ -stopping time + π such that π = π + π« -q.s. Moreover, for any such π + , the π -elds β±π and β±π++ dier only by π« -polar sets. β Proof. (i) Note that π is of the form π = π π‘π 1Ξπ for Ξπ = {π = π‘π } β β±π‘π forming a partition of such that
Ξ©.
Ξπ = Ξβπ π -a.s.
Since
F β π½β π by Lemma 4.4, we can nd Ξβπ β β±π‘β
π
and the rst assertion follows by taking
π β := π 1(βͺπ Ξβπ )π +
β
π‘π 1Ξβπ .
π
π΄ β β±π . By the rst part, there exists an π½β -stopping time (ππ΄ )β β β² β that (ππ΄ ) = ππ΄ := π 1π΄ + π 1π΄π π -a.s. Moreover, we choose π΄ β β±π β² that π΄ = π΄ π -a.s. Then ( ) π΄β := π΄β² β© {π β = π } βͺ {(ππ΄ )β = π β < π }
Let such such
π΄β β β±πββ and π΄ = π΄β π -a.s. A similar but simpler argument shows β β² β² that for given Ξ β β±π β we can nd Ξ β β±π such that Ξ = Ξ π -a.s. + π (ii) If π is an F- (resp. π½ -) stopping time, we can nd π taking countπ + ably many values such that π decreases to π and since F (π½ ) is right + + continuous, β±π π (β±π π ) decreases to β±π (β±π ). As a result, we may assume without loss of generality that π takes countably many values. β Let π = π π‘π 1Ξπ , where Ξπ β β±π‘π . The denition of F shows that there + + + exist Ξπ β β±π‘ such that Ξπ = Ξπ π« -q.s. and the rst part follows. The proof π satises
of the second part is as in (i); we now have quasi-sure instead of almost-sure relations.
π is a stopping taking nitely many values (π‘π )1β€πβ€π , we can βπ time β β dene β°π (π) := π=1 β°π‘π (π)1{π=π‘π } . We have the following generalization If
of (4.1).
Lemma 4.8. Let π be an π½β -stopping time taking nitely many values. Then β²
β°πβ (π) = ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±πβ ] π β² βπ«(β±πβ ,π )
13
π -a.s.
for all π β π«.
Proof.
π β π« and ππ‘β := β°π‘β (π). Moreover, let (π‘π )1β€πβ€π be the values β of π and Ξπ := {π = π‘π } β β±π‘ . π β² (i) We rst prove the inequality β₯. Given π β π« , it follows from (4.2) β β² β that {ππ‘ }1β€πβ€π is a π -supermartingale in (β±π‘ )1β€πβ€π and so the (discreteπ π β πβ² β time) optional sampling theorem [9, Theorem V.11] implies ππ β₯ πΈ [πβ£β±π ] β² β² β π -a.s. In particular, this also holds π -a.s. for all π β π«(β±π , π ), hence the Let
claim follows. (ii) We now show the inequality β€. Note that
(Ξπ )1β€πβ€π
form an
β±πβ -measurable
partition of
β²
ππ‘βπ 1Ξπ β€ ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±πβ ]1Ξπ
Ξ©.
π=
βπ
π=1 π‘π 1Ξπ and that
It suces to show that
π -a.s.
for
1 β€ π β€ π.
π β² βπ«(β±πβ ,π )
In the sequel, we x
πΒ― β
π
and show that for each
π«(β±πβ , π ) such that πΒ― (π΄ β© Ξπ ) = π β² (π΄ β© Ξπ )
In view of (4.1) and
π β² β π«(β±π‘βπ , π )
for all
π΄ β β±πβ .
(4.8)
β²
β²
there exists
πΈ π [πβ£β±πβ ]1Ξπ = πΈ π [πβ£β±π‘βπ ]1Ξπ π β² -a.s.,
it will then
follow that
Β―
β²
ππ‘βπ 1Ξπ = ess supπ πΈ π [π1Ξπ β£β±π‘βπ ] β€ ess supπ πΈ π [π1Ξπ β£β±πβ ] π -a.s. π β² βπ«(β±π‘β ,π ) π
πΒ― βπ«(β±πβ ,π )
as claimed. Indeed, given
π β² β π«(β±π‘βπ , π ),
we dene
πΒ― (π΄) := π β² (π΄ β© Ξπ ) + π (π΄ β Ξπ ),
π΄ β β±πβ ,
(4.9)
Ξ β β±πβ , then Ξ β© Ξπ = Ξ β© {π = π‘π } β β±π‘βπ π β² (Ξ β© Ξπ ) = π (Ξ β© Ξπ ). Hence πΒ― = π on β±πβ .
then (4.8) is obviously satised. If and
π β² β π«(β±π‘βπ , π )
yields
Moreover, we observe that (4.9) can be stated as
] [ πΒ― (π΄) = πΈ π π β² (π΄β£β±π‘βπ )1Ξπ + π (π΄β£β±π‘βπ )1Ξππ ,
π΄ β β±πβ ,
which is a special case of the pasting (3.2) applied with
πΒ― β π«
by Assumption 4.1 and we have
πΒ― β π«(β±πβ , π )
π2 := π .
Hence
as desired.
For the next result, we recall that stability under pasting refers to stopping times with nitely many values rather than general ones (Denition 3.2).
Lemma 4.9. The set π« is stable under π½-pasting. Proof. Let π β π― (π½), then π is of the form π=
β
π‘π 1Ξπ ,
Ξπ := {π = π‘π } β β±π‘π ,
π
β [0, π ] are distinct and the sets Ξπ form a partition of Ξ©. Moreover, Ξ β β± π and π1 , π2 β π«(β±π , ]π ), then we have to show that the measure [ π πΈ π1 ( β
β£β±π )1Ξ + π2 ( β
β£β±π )1Ξπ is an element of π« .
where π‘π let
14
(i) We start by proving that for any such that
π΄=
π΄β² holds
π΄ β β±π
π«(β±π , π )-q.s. Consider βͺ π΄ = (π΄ β© Ξπ ).
there exists
π΄β² β β±πβ β© β±π
the disjoint union
π
π΄ β© Ξπ β β±π‘π since π΄ β β±π . As F β π½β by Lemma 4.4, π΄π β β±π‘βπ and a π -nullset ππ , disjoint from π΄π , such that π
Here set
π΄ β© Ξπ = π΄π βͺ ππ . (It is
not
there exist a
(4.10)
necessary to subtract another nullset on the right hand side.) We
π΄β² := βͺπ π΄π , then π΄β² β β±πβ and clearly π΄ = π΄β² π -a.s. Let us check that β² latter also holds π«(β±π , π )-q.s. For this, it suces to show that π΄ β β±π .
dene the
Indeed, by the construction of (4.10),
{ π΄π β β±π‘βπ β β±π‘π , π = π, π΄π β© {π = π‘π } = β
β β±π‘π , π= β π; i.e., each set
π΄π
is in
β±π .
Hence,
π΄β² β β±π ,
which completes the proof of (i).
β For later use, we dene the π½ -stopping time
(ππ΄ )β := π 1(π΄β² )π +
β
π‘ π 1π΄ π
π
)β
π«(β±π , π )-q.s. (ii) Using the previous construction for π΄ = Ξ©, we see in β β β there exist Ξπ β β±π‘ such that Ξπ = Ξπ holds π«(β±π , π )-q.s. π β the π½ -stopping time β π β := π 1(βͺπ Ξβπ )π + π‘π 1Ξβπ
and note that
(ππ΄
= ππ΄
holds
particular that We also dene
π
πβ = π. β (iii) We can now show that β±π β and β±π may be identied (when π, π1 , π2 β² are xed). Indeed, if π΄ β β±π , we let π΄ be as in (i) and set ( ) π΄β := π΄β² β© {π β = π } βͺ {(ππ΄ )β = π β < π }.
which
π«(β±π , π )-q.s.
satises
π΄β β β±πββ and π΄ = π΄β holds π«(β±π , π )-q.s. Conversely, given π΄β β β±πββ , β we nd π΄ β β±π such that π΄ = π΄ holds π«(β±π , π )-q.s. We conclude that ] [ ] [ πΈ π π1 ( β
β£β±π )1Ξ + π2 ( β
β£β±π )1Ξπ = πΈ π π1 ( β
β£β±πββ )1Ξβ + π2 ( β
β£β±πββ )1(Ξβ )π . Then
The right hand side is an element of
π«
by the stability under
We can now prove the optional sampling theorem for particular, this establishes the
π½-time-consistency
stopping times.
15
of
{β°π‘ }
π½β -pasting.
β° -martingales; along general
in
F-
Theorem 4.10. Let 0 β€ π β€ π β€ π be stopping times, β°(π) be the cΓ dlΓ g β° -martingale associated with π . Then π -a.s.
β²
β°π (π) = ess supπ πΈ π [β°π (π)β£β±π ] π β² βπ«(β±π ,π )
π β β,
and let
for all π β π«
(4.11)
and in particular π -a.s.
β²
β°π (π) = ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±π ] π β² βπ«(β±π ,π )
for all π β π«.
(4.12)
Moreover, there exists for each π β π« a sequence ππ β π«(β±π , π ) such that π -a.s.
β°π (π) = lim πΈ ππ [πβ£β±π ] πββ
(4.13)
with an increasing limit. Proof.
Fix
π βπ«
and let
π := β°(π).
(i) We rst show the inequality β₯ in (4.12).
π
is an
(F, π β² )-supermartingale
By Proposition 4.5(i),
π β² β π«(β±π , π ).
for all
Hence the (usual)
optional sampling theorem implies the claim. (ii) In the next two steps, we show the inequality β€ in (4.12). In view of Lemma 4.7(ii) we may assume that
(π + 1/π) β§ π
π
also assume that
π
π½+ -stopping time, and then π β₯ 1. For the time being, we
is an
β is an π½ -stopping time for each
takes nitely many values. Let
π·π := {π2βπ : π = 0, 1, . . . } βͺ {π } and dene
π π (π) := inf{π‘ β π·π : π‘ β₯ π(π) + 1/π} β§ π. π½β -stopping time taking nitely many values and π π (π) deπ creases to π(π) for all π β Ξ©. Since the range of {π, (π )π } is countable, it β follows from Proposition 4.5(ii) that β°π π (π) β ππ π -a.s. Since β₯πβ₯πΏ1 < β,
Each
ππ
is an
π«
the backward supermartingale convergence theorem [9, Theorem V.30] implies that this convergence holds also in
πΏ1 (π )
and that
ππ = lim πΈ π [β°πβπ (π)β£β±π ] π -a.s., πββ
where, by monotonicity, the a subsequence. sequence
π -a.s.
(4.14)
convergence holds without passing to
By Lemma 4.8 and Lemma 3.4, there exists for each
(πππ )πβ₯1
in
π«(β±πβπ , π )
such that β²
π
β°πβπ (π) = ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±πβπ ] = lim πΈ ππ [πβ£β±πβπ ] π -a.s., πββ
π β² βπ«(β±πβπ ,π )
where the limit is increasing. Moreover, using that
{ β±π+π+1 = π΄ β β±πβ : π΄ β© {π π+1 < π‘} β β±π‘β 16
for
} 0β€π‘β€π ,
π
a
π π > π π+1 on {π π < π } is seen to imply that β±π+π+1 β β±πβπ . π+1 and Lemma 4.7(ii) we conclude that with π β€ π
the fact that Together
π« -q.s.
β±π β β±ππ+1 = β±π+π+1 β β±πβπ
and hence
π«(β±π , π ) β π«(β±πβπ , π ) (4.15)
for all
π.
Now monotone convergence yields β²
π
πΈ π [β°πβπ (π)β£β±π ] = lim πΈ ππ [πβ£β±π ]
β€ ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±π ] π -a.s.
πββ
π β² βπ«(β±π ,π )
In view of (4.14), this ends the proof of (4.12) for
π
taking nitely many
values. (ii') Now let
ππ
π
be general. We approximate
π
by the decreasing sequence
:= inf{π‘ β π·π : π‘ β₯ π} β§ π of stopping times with nitely many values. β°ππ (π) β‘ πππ β ππ π -a.s. since π is cΓ dlΓ g. The same arguments as
Then
for (4.14) show that
ππ = lim πΈ π [β°ππ (π)β£β±π ] π -a.s.
(4.16)
πββ
By the two previous steps we have the representation (4.12) for Lemma 3.4, it follows from the stability under there exists for each
π
a sequence
(πππ )πβ₯1
in
ππ.
As in
π½-pasting (Lemma 4.9) that π«(β±ππ , π ) β π«(β±π , π ) such
that β²
π
β°ππ (π) = ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±ππ ] = lim πΈ ππ [πβ£β±ππ ] π -a.s., πββ
π β² βπ«(β±ππ ,π )
where the limit is increasing and hence β²
π
πΈ π [β°ππ (π)β£β±π ] = lim πΈ ππ [πβ£β±π ]
β€ ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±π ] π -a.s.
πββ
π β² βπ«(β±π ,π )
Together with (4.16), this completes the proof of (4.12). (iii) We now prove (4.13). Since
π
is general, the claim does not follow
from the stability under pasting. Instead, we use the construction of (ii'). Indeed, we have obtained
πππ β π«(β±ππ , π )
such that
π
ππ = lim lim πΈ ππ [πβ£β±π ] π -a.s. πββ πββ
π. Since π π is an π½-stopping time taking nitely many values and since β±π β β±ππ , it follows from the stability under π½-pasting (applied to π π ) that πβ² β² the set {πΈ [πβ£β±π ] : π β π«(β±π π , π )} is π -a.s. upward ltering, exactly as in the proof of Lemma 3.4. In view of π«(β±π π , π ) β π«(β±π π+1 , π ), it follows (π ) β π«(β± that for each π β₯ 1 there exists π π π , π ) such that Fix
πΈπ
(π )
π
[πβ£β±π ] = max max πΈ ππ [πβ£β±π ] π -a.s. 1β€πβ€π 1β€πβ€π
17
Since
π«(β±ππ , π ) β π«(β±π , π ),
this yields the claim.
β°π (π) and β°π (π) as essential for π . The inequality β€ is then
(iv) To prove (4.11), we rst express suprema by using (4.12) both for
π
and
immediate. The converse inequality follows by a monotone convergence argument exactly as in the proof of Proposition 3.6(i), except that the increasing sequence is now obtained from (4.13) instead of Lemma 3.4.
4.3
Decomposition and 2BSDE for
β° -Martingales
The next result contains the semimartingale decomposition of each
π βπ«
β°(π)
under
and can be seen as an analogue of the optional decomposition [19]
used in mathematical nance.
In the context of
πΊ-expectations,
such a
result has also been referred to as πΊ-martingale representation theorem; see [16, 34, 35, 37]. Those results are ultimately based on the PDE description of the
πΊ-expectation
and are more precise than ours; in particular, they
(πΎ π )π βπ« (but 1 see Remark 4.17). On the other hand, we obtain an πΏ -theory whereas those
provide a single increasing process
πΎ
results require more integrability for
rather than a family
π.
Proposition 4.11. Let π β β. There exist β« (i) an F-predictable process π π with 0π β£ππ π β£2 πβ¨π΅β©π < β π« -q.s., (ii) a family (πΎ π )π βπ« of π½π -predictable processes such that all paths of πΎ π are cΓ dlΓ g nondecreasing and πΈ π [β£πΎππ β£] < β, such that (πβ«) π‘
β°π‘ (π) = β°0 (π) +
ππ π ππ΅π β πΎπ‘π
0
for all 0 β€ π‘ β€ π, π -a.s.
(4.17)
for all π β π« . The process π π is unique up to {ππ Γ π, π β π«}-polar sets and πΎ π is unique up to π -evanescence. Proof. We shall use arguments similar to the proof of [33, Theorem 4.5]. Let
π β π«.
It follows from Proposition 4.5(i) that
π := β°(π)
is an
π
(π½ , π )-supermartingale. We apply the Doob-Meyer decomposition in the π ltered space (Ξ©, π½ , π ) which satises the usual conditions of right continuπ π and ity and completeness. Thus we obtain an (π½ , π )-local martingale π π π an π½ -predictable increasing integrable process πΎ , cΓ dlΓ g and satisfying π0π = πΎ0π = 0, such that π = π0 + π π β πΎ π . (π, π΅) has the predictable representation π π such that exists an π½ -predictable process π (πβ«) π = π0 + π π ππ΅ β πΎ π .
By Lemma 4.4, Hence there
18
property in
π
π½
.
The next step is to replace calling that
β«
π΅
ππ
by a process
ππ
independent of
is a continuous local martingale under each
π π πβ¨π΅β©π = β¨π, π΅β©π = π΅π β
(πβ«)
π,
π.
Re-
we have
(πβ«)
π΅ ππ β
πβ ππ΅
π -a.s.
(4.18)
(Here and below, the statements should be read componentwise.) The last two integrals are ItΓ΄ integrals under
π , but they can also be dened pathwise
since the integrands are left limits of cΓ dlΓ g processes which are bounded path-by-path.
This is a classical construction from [3, Theorem 7.14]; see
also [18] for the same result in modern notation.
To make explicit that
β«the resulting process is π½-adapted, we recall the procedure for the example πβ ππ΅ . One rst denes for each π β₯ 1 the sequence of F-stopping times π := inf{π‘ β₯ π π : β£π β π π β£ β₯ 2βπ }. Then one denes πΌ π by π0π := 0 and ππ+1 π‘ ππ π πΌπ‘π := ππππ (π΅π‘ β π΅πππ ) +
πβ1 β
π ππππ (π΅ππ+1 β π΅πππ )
for
π πππ < π‘ β€ ππ+1 ,
π β₯ 0;
π=0 clearly
πΌπ
is again
F-adapted and all its paths are cΓ dlΓ g. Finally, we dene πΌπ‘ := lim sup πΌπ‘π ,
0 β€ π‘ β€ π.
πββ
Then
πΌ
is again
F-adapted and it is a consequence of the Burkholder-Davis-
Gundy inequalities that
β« π (π ) π‘ sup πΌπ‘ β πβ ππ΅ β 0 π -a.s.
0β€π‘β€π for each
π.
0
Thus, outside a
exists as a limit uniformly in
π« -polar π‘ and πΌ
set, the limsup in the denition of has cΓ dlΓ g paths. Since
π« -polar
πΌ
sets
β±0 , we may redene πΌ := 0 on the exceptional set. Now β« πΌ is cΓ dlΓ g F-adapted and coincides with the ItΓ΄ integral (π ) πβ ππ΅ up to π -evanescence, for all π β π« . β« (π ) π΅ ππ and obtain a denition We proceed similarly with the integral
are contained in
for the right hand side of (4.18) which is
F-adapted, continuous and inde-
β¨π, π΅β© simultaneously for all π β π« , π Λ = πβ¨π΅β©/ππ‘ be the (left) derivative in time of β¨π΅β©, then π Λ is π½β -predictable and π>0 π -valued π Γ ππ‘-a.e. for all π β π« π by the denition of π«π . Finally, π := π Λβ1 πβ¨π, π΅β©/ππ‘ is an F-predictable
pendent of
π.
Thus we have dened
and we do the same for
β¨π΅β©.
Let
process such that
(πβ«)
π = π0 +
π π ππ΅ β πΎ π
We note that the integral is taken under to dene it for all
π βπ«
simultaneously.
19
π -a.s. π;
for all
π β π«.
see also Remark 4.17 for a way
The previous proof shows that a decomposition of the type (4.17) ex-
(π½, π«)-supermartingales,
ists for all cΓ dlΓ g
and not just for
β° -martingales.
As a special case of Proposition 4.11, we obtain a representation for symmetric
β° -martingales.
The following can be seen as a generalization of the
corresponding results for
πΊ-expectations
given in [34, 35, 37].
Corollary 4.12. Let π β β be such that βπ β β. The following are equivalent: (i) β°(π) is a symmetric β° -martingale; i.e., β°(βπ) = ββ°(π) π« -q.s. β« (ii) There exists an F-predictable process π π with 0π β£ππ π β£2 πβ¨π΅β©π < β π« -q.s. such that π‘
β«
ππ π ππ΅π
β°π‘ (π) = β°0 (π) + 0
for all 0 β€ π‘ β€ π, π« -q.s.,
where the integral can be dened universally for all π and π π ππ΅ is an (π½, π )-martingale for all π β π« . In particular, any symmetric β° -martingale has continuous trajectories π« -q.s. β«
Proof.
The implication (ii)β(i) is clear from Proposition 4.5(iii).
Con-
β°(π) and ββ°(π) are π« -martingale. It follows that π β‘ 0 and (4.17) becomes satisfy πΎ
versely, given (i), Proposition 4.5(i) yields that both
π« -supermartingales,
hence
β°(π)
is a (true)
πΎ π have to ππ΅ . β«In particular, the stochastic setting π π ππ΅ := β°(π) β β°0 (π).
the increasing processes
(π )
β«
β°(π) = β°0 (π) +
dened universally by
Remark 4.13.
ππ
integral can be
(a) Without the martingale condition in Corollary 4.12(ii),
the implication (ii)β(i) would fail even for
π« = {π0 },
in which case Corol-
lary 4.12 is simply the Brownian martingale representation theorem.
β°(π) need not be a π« -modication of the famπ‘ β [0, π ]}; in fact, the β° -martingale in Example 4.6 is symmetric.
(b) Even if it is symmetric,
β ily {β°π‘ (π),
However, the situation changes if the symmetry assumption is imposed di-
{β°π‘β (π)}. π‘ β [0, π ].
rectly on for all
β
We call
{β°π‘β (π)} symmetric if β°π‘β (βπ) = ββ°π‘β (π) π« -q.s.
If {β°π‘β (π)} symmetric, then β°(π) is a symmetric β° -martingale and a π« -modication of {β°π‘β (π)}.
Indeed, the assumption implies that each
π βπ«
and so the process
is the usual cΓ dlΓ g
β°(π)
π -modication
Next, we represent the pair
of
{β°π‘β (π)}
is an
(π½β , π )-martingale
for
of right limits (cf. Proposition 4.5(ii))
{β°π‘β (π)},
(β°(π), π π )
for all
π.
from Proposition 4.11 as the
solution of a 2BSDE. The following denition is essentially from [32].
Denition 4.14. values in
β Γ βπ
Let
such
π β πΏ1π« and consider a pair (π, π) of processes with that π is cΓ dlΓ g F-adapted while π is F-predictable 20
and
β«π
β£ππ β£2 πβ¨π΅β©π < β π« -q.s.
0
Then
(π, π)
is called a
π 2BSDE (4.19) if there exists a family (πΎ )π βπ« of π π processes satisfying πΈ [β£πΎπ β£] < β such that (πβ«) π
ππ‘ = π β
ππ ππ΅π + πΎππ β πΎπ‘π ,
0 β€ π‘ β€ π,
π
π½
solution
of the
-adapted increasing
π -a.s.
for all
π βπ«
π‘ (4.19) and such that the following minimality condition holds for all
ess inf π
π β² βπ«(β±π‘ ,π )
] β²[ β² β² πΈ π πΎππ β πΎπ‘π β±π‘ = 0 π -a.s.
We note that (4.20) is essentially the
for all
0 β€ π‘ β€ π:
π β π«.
β° -martingale condition (4.4):
(4.20)
if the
π can be aggregated into a single process πΎ and πΎ β β, then processes πΎ π βπΎ = β°(βπΎπ ). Regarding the aggregation of (πΎ π ), see also Remark 4.17. A second notion is needed to state the main result.
π
is said to be
under
π
for all
of class (D,π« )
π β π«,
where
if the family
π
{ππ }π
runs through all
A cΓ dlΓ g process
is uniformly integrable
F-stopping times.
example, we have seen in Corollary 4.12 that all symmetric
As an
β° -martingales
are of class (D,π« ). (Of course, it is important here that we work with a nite
π .) For π β [1, β), we π β := {π β β : β£πβ£π β β}.
time horizon well as
dene
β₯πβ₯πΏπ =: supπ βπ« πΈ[β£πβ£π ]1/π π«
as
Lemma 4.15. If π β βπ for some π β (1, β), then β°(π) is of class (D,π« ). Proof.
Let
π β π«.
If
π
is an
F-stopping time, Jensen's inequality and (4.12)
yield that β²
β£β°π (π)β£π β€ ess supπ πΈ π [β£πβ£π β£β±π ] = β°π (β£πβ£π ) π -a.s. π β² βπ«(β±π ,π )
In particular,
β₯β°π (π)β₯ππΏπ (π ) β€ πΈ π [β°π (β£πβ£π )]
and thus Lemma 4.4 yields β²
β₯β°π (π)β₯ππΏπ (π ) β€ πΈ π [β°π (β£πβ£π )β£β±0 ] β€ ess supπ πΈ π [β°π (β£πβ£π )β£β±0 ] π -a.s. π β² βπ«(β±0 ,π )
The right hand side
π -a.s. equals β°0 (β£πβ£π ) by (4.11), so we conclude with (4.7)
that β²
β₯β°π (π)β₯ππΏπ (π ) β€ β°0 (β£πβ£π ) β€ sup πΈ π [β£πβ£π ] = β₯πβ₯ππΏπ < β π -a.s. π β² βπ«
{β°π (π)}π is bounded in πΏπ (π ) under π . This holds for all π β π« .
Therefore, the family formly integrable
We can now state the main result of this section.
21
π«
and in particular uni-
Theorem 4.16. Let π β β. (i) The pair (β°(π), π π ) is the minimal solution of the 2BSDE (4.19); i.e., if (π, π) is another solution, then β°(π) β€ π π« -q.s. (ii) If (π, π) is a solution of (4.19) such that π is of class (D,π« ), then (π, π) = (β°(π), π π ). In particular, if π β βπ for some π > 1, then (β°(π), π π ) is the unique solution of (4.19) in the class (D,π« ). Proof. (i) Let π β π« . To show that (β°(π), π π ) is a solution, we only have to show that
πΎπ
from the decomposition (4.17) satises the minimality con-
dition (4.20). We denote this decomposition by
β°(π)
It follows from Proposition 4.5(i) that As
πΎ π β₯ 0,
is
β°(π) = β°0 (π) + π π β πΎ π . π an (π½ , π )-supermartingale.
we deduce that
π
β°0 (π) + π π β₯ β°(π) β₯ πΈ π [πβ£π½ ] π -a.s., π
π
πΈ π [πβ£π½ ] denotes the cΓ dlΓ g (π½ , π )-martingale with terminal value π . Hence π π is a local π -martingale bounded from below by a π -martingale π is an (F, π )-supermartingale by a standard argument using and thus π Fatou's lemma. This holds for all π β π« . Therefore, (4.4) yields where
β²
0 = β°π‘ (π) β ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±π‘ ] π β² βπ«(β±
= ess inf
π
π β² βπ«(β±π‘ ,π )
πΈ
πβ²
[
π‘ ,π )
] β°π‘ (π) β β°π (π) β±π‘
] β² β² β² β²[ β² = ess inf π πΈ π ππ‘π β πππ + πΎππ β πΎπ‘π β±π‘ β² π βπ«(β±π‘ ,π ) ] β²[ β² β² β₯ ess inf π πΈ π πΎππ β πΎπ‘π β±π‘ π -a.s. for all π β π«. π β² βπ«(β±π‘ ,π )
Since
πΎπ
β²
is nondecreasing, the last expression is also nonnegative and (4.20)
follows. Thus
(β°(π), π π )
is a solution.
(π, π) be another solution of (4.19). It (F, π )-supermartingale for all π β π« . β« (π ) As above, the integrability of π implies that π0 + π ππ΅ is bounded below by a π -martingale. Noting also that π0 is π -a.s. equal to a constant β« (π ) π ππ΅ and π are (F, π )-supermartingales. by Lemma 4.4, we deduce that Since π is cΓ dlΓ g and ππ = π , the minimality property in Proposition 4.5(i) shows that π β₯ β°(π) π« -q.s. β« (π ) π ππ΅ is a true π -martingale (ii) If in addition π is of class (D,π« ), then To prove the minimality, let
follows from (4.19) that
π
is a local
by the Doob-Meyer theorem and we have
] β²[ β² β² 0 = ess inf π πΈ π πΎππ β πΎπ‘π β±π‘ π β² βπ«(β±π‘ ,π )
β²
= ππ‘ β ess supπ πΈ π [πβ£β±π‘ ] π β² βπ«(β±π‘ ,π )
= ππ‘ β β°π‘ (π) π -a.s. 22
for all
π β π«.
The last statement in the theorem follows from Lemma 4.15.
Remark 4.17.
If we use axioms of set theory stronger than the usual ZFC,
such as the Continuum Hypothesis, then the integrals
β« {(π ) π ππ΅}π βπ«
can
be aggregated into a single (universally measurable) continuous process, denoted by
β«
π ππ΅ ,
for any
π
which is
π΅ -integrable
under all
π β π«.
This
follows from a recent result on pathwise stochastic integration, cf. [25]. In
(πΎ π )π βπ« of increasing β« πΎ := β°0 (π) β β°(π) + π π ππ΅ .
Proposition 4.11, we can then aggregate the family processes into a single process
πΎ
by setting
Moreover, we can strengthen Theorem 4.16 by asking for a universal process
πΎ
the Denition 4.14 of the 2BSDE.
4.4
Application to Superhedging and Replication
We now turn to the interpretation of the previous results for the super-
π problem. Let π» be an β -valued π½-predictable process satisfying β«hedging π 2 β£ πβ¨π΅β©π < β π« -q.s. Then π» is called an admissible trading strategy 0 β£π» β«π (π ) if π» ππ΅ is a π -supermartingale for all π β π« . (We do not insist that the integral be dened without reference to π , since this is not necessary economically.
But see also Remark 4.17.)
As usual in continuous-time -
nance, this denition excludes doubling strategies. proof of Theorem 4.16 that
ππ
is admissible for
We have seen in the
π β β.
The minimality
property in Proposition 4.5(i) and the existence of the decomposition (4.17) yield the following conclusion:
β°0 (π) is the minimal β±0 -measurable initial π ; i.e., β°0 (π) is the π« -q.s. minimal β±0 -
capital which allows to superhedge measurable random variable
π»
π0
such that there exists an admissible strategy
satisfying
(πβ«) π
π»π ππ΅π β₯ π
π0 +
π -a.s.
for all
π β π«.
0 Moreover, the overshoot
πΎπ
for the strategy
ππ
satises the minimality
condition (4.20). As seen in Example 4.6, the
β±0 -superhedging
price
β°0 (π)
need not be
a constant, and therefore it is debatable whether it is a good choice for a conservative price, in particular if the raw ltration
π½β
is seen as the initial
information structure for the model. Indeed, the following illustration shows that knowledge of
β±0
can be quite signicant. Consider a collection
positive constants and
π« = {π πΌ : πΌ β‘ ππ
for some
π}.
(Such a set
(ππ ) of π« can
indeed satisfy the assumptions of this section.) In this model, knowledge of
β±0
β±0 contains { } β π΄π := lim sup π‘β1 β¨π΅β©π‘ = lim inf π‘β1 β¨π΅β©π‘ = ππ β β±0+
completely removes the volatility uncertainty since
π‘β0
π‘β0
23
the sets
which form a
π« -q.s.
partition of
Ξ©.
Hence, one may want to use the more
conservative choice
π₯ = β°0β (π) = sup πΈ π [π] = inf{π¦ β β : π¦ β₯ β°0 (π)} π βπ«
β° -martingale as follows. β±0β be the smallest π -eld containing the π« -polar sets, then β±0β is trivial π« -q.s. If we adjoin β±0β as a new initial state to the ltration π½, we can extend β°(π) by setting as the price. This value can be embedded into the
Let
β°0β (π) := sup πΈ π [π],
π β β.
π βπ« The resulting process
{β°π‘ (π)}π‘β[β0,π ]
satises the properties from Proposi-
π₯ = β°0β (π) β±0β -superhedging price of π . (Of course, all this becomes superuous β the case where β°(π) is a π« -modication of {β°π‘ (π)}.)
tion 4.5 in the extended ltration and in particular the constant is the in
In the remainder of the section, we discuss replicable claims and adopt the previously mentioned conservative choice.
Denition 4.18. a constant
π« -q.s.
π₯ββ
A random variable and an
π β β is called replicable if there exist β«π 2 πβ¨π΅β© < β β£π» β£ π π 0
F-predictable process π» with
such that
(πβ«) π
π =π₯+
π»π‘ ππ΅π‘
π -a.s.
for all
π βπ«
(4.21)
0 and such that
(π )
β«
π» ππ΅
is an
(F, π )-martingale
for all
π β π«.
The martingale assumption is needed to avoid strategies which throw away money. Moreover, as in Corollary 4.12, the stochastic integral can necessarily be dened without reference to
π,
by setting
β«
π» ππ΅ := β°(π) β π₯.
The following result is an analogue of the standard characterization of replicable claims in incomplete markets (e.g., [8, p. 182]).
Proposition 4.19. Let π β β be such that βπ β β. The following are equivalent: (i) β°(π) is a symmetric β° -martingale and β°0 (π) is constant π« -q.s. (ii) π is replicable. (iii) There exists π₯ β β such that πΈ π [π] = π₯ for all π β π« . Proof.
The equivalence (i)β(ii) is immediate from Corollary 4.12 and the
implication (ii)β(iii) follows by taking expectations in (4.21). prove (iii)β(ii).
By (4.7) we have
Hence we
β°0 (βπ) β€ supπ βπ« πΈ π [βπ] = βπ₯
24
and
β°(π) β€ π₯. Thus, β°(π) show that (πβ«) π π βπ ππ΅ βπ β€ βπ₯ +
similarly
β°(βπ)
π β π«,
given
the decompositions (4.17) of
and
(πβ«) π
π β€π₯+
and
π π ππ΅
π -a.s.
(4.22)
0
0
β« (π ) π (π βπ 0
+ π π ) ππ΅ π -a.s. As we π and π βπ know from the proof of Theorem 4.16 that the integrals of π β« β« π π (π ) βπ ππ΅ = β(π ) π are supermartingales, it follows that 0 π 0 π ππ΅ π -a.s. β« π (π ) π Now (4.22) yields that π = π₯ + 0 π ππ΅ . In view of (iii), this integral
Adding the inequalities yields
0 β€
is a supermartingale with constant expectation, hence a martingale.
5
Uniqueness of Time-Consistent Extensions
In the introduction, we have claimed that
{β°π‘β (π)}
as in (1.2) is the natural
dynamic extension of the static sublinear expectation
π 7β supπ βπ« πΈ π [π].
In this section, we add some substance to this claim by showing that the extension is unique under suitable assumptions. (We note that by Proposition 3.6, the question of existence is essentially reduced to the technical problem of aggregation.) The setup is as follows. We x a nonempty set on
(Ξ©, β±πβ ); it is not important whether π«
π«
of probability measures
consists of martingale laws. On the
other hand, we impose additional structure on the set of random variables. In this section, we consider a chain of vector spaces
β = β0 β βπ β βπ‘ β βπ =: β β πΏ1π« , We assume that addition
π
π, π β βπ‘
implies
is bounded. As before,
(βπ‘ )0β€π‘β€π
satisfying
0 β€ π β€ π‘ β€ π.
π β§ π, π β¨ π β βπ‘ , and ππ β βπ‘ if in β should be seen as the set of nancial
βπ‘ will serve as test functions; the main example βπ‘ = β β© πΏ1π« (β±π‘β ). We consider a family (πΌπ‘ )0β€π‘β€π of
claims. The elements of to have in mind is mappings
πΌπ‘ : β β πΏ1π« (β±π‘β ) (πΌπ‘ ) as a dynamic extension of πΌ0 . Our aim is to nd conditions under which πΌ0 already determines the whole family (πΌπ‘ ), or more precisely, determines πΌπ‘ (π) up to a π« -polar set for all π β β and 0 β€ π‘ β€ π .
and think of
Denition 5.1. if for all
(πΌπ‘ )0β€π‘β€π π β β,
The family
π‘ β [0, π ]
and
πΌπ‘ (ππ) = πΌπ‘ (π)π π« -q.s.
is called
(βπ‘ )-positively
for all bounded nonnegative
Note that this property excludes trivial extensions of
πΌ0 ,
we can always dene the (time-consistent) extension
{ πΌ0 (π), 0 β€ π‘ < π, πΌπ‘ (π) := π, π‘ = π, 25
πΌ0 .
homogeneous π β βπ‘ . Indeed, given
but this family choices of
(πΌπ‘ )
is not
(βπ‘ )-positively
homogeneous for nondegenerate
(βπ‘ ).
To motivate the next denition, we rst recall that in the classical setup under a reference measure
πβ ,
strict monotonicity of
tion for uniqueness of extensions; i.e., should imply that
πΌ0 (π) > πΌ0 (π ).
πΌ0 is the crucial condiπ β₯ π πβ -a.s. and πβ {π > π } > 0
In our setup with singular measures,
πΌ0 (β
) = supπ βπ« πΈ π [ β
], it is completely reasonable to have random variables π β₯ π satisfying πΌ0 (π) = πΌ0 (π ) and π1 {π > π } > 0 for some π1 β π« , since the suprema can be attained at some π2 β π« whose support is disjoint from {π > π }. the corresponding condition is too strong. E.g., for
In the following denition, we allow for an additional localization by a test function.
Denition 5.2.
(βπ‘ )-locally strictly monotone if for every π‘ β [0, π ] and any π, π β βπ‘ satisfying π β₯ π π« -q.s. and π (π > π ) > 0 for some π β π« , there exists π β βπ‘ such that 0 β€ π β€ 1 and We say that
πΌ0
is
πΌ0 (ππ ) > πΌ0 (π π ). Here the delicate point is the regularity required for tempted to try
π.
Indeed, one is
π := 1{π>π +πΏ} (for some constant πΏ > 0), but in applications βπ‘ may exclude this choice and require a more rened
the denition of
construction. We defer this task to Proposition 5.5 and rst show how local strict monotonicity yields uniqueness.
Proposition 5.3. Let πΌ0 be (βπ‘ )-locally strictly monotone. Then there exists at most one extension of πΌ0 to a family (πΌπ‘ )0β€π‘β€π which is (βπ‘ )-positively homogeneous and satises πΌπ‘ (β) β βπ‘ and πΌ0 β πΌπ‘ = πΌ0 on β. Λ π‘ ) be two such extensions and suppose for contradicProof. Let (πΌπ‘ ) and (πΌ Λ π‘ (π) for some π β β; i.e., there exists π β π« such that πΌπ‘ (π) β= πΌ Λ π‘ (π)} > 0 or π {πΌπ‘ (π) < πΌ Λ π‘ (π)} > 0. Without loss of π {πΌπ‘ (π) > πΌ
tion that either
generality, we focus on the rst case. Dene
π := Then over,
([ ] ) Λ π‘ (π) β¨ 0 β§ 1. πΌπ‘ (π) β πΌ
π β βπ‘ , since βπ‘ is a lattice containing the constant functions; moreΛ π‘ (π)}. Setting π β² := ππ and 0 β€ π β€ 1 and {π = 0} = {πΌπ‘ (π) β€ πΌ
using the positive homogeneity, we arrive at
Λ π‘ (π β² ) πΌπ‘ (π β² ) β₯ πΌ
and
{ } Λ π‘ (π β² ) > 0. π πΌπ‘ (π β² ) > πΌ
π β βπ‘ such that 0 β€ π β€ 1 ( ) ( ) Λ π‘ (π β² )π . Now πΌ0 = πΌ0 β πΌπ‘ yields that πΌ0 πΌπ‘ (π β² )π > πΌ0 πΌ ( ) ( ) Λ π‘ (π β² )π = πΌ Λ 0 (π β² π ), πΌ0 (π β² π ) = πΌ0 πΌπ‘ (π β² )π > πΌ0 πΌ By local strict monotonicity there exists
which contradicts
Λ0. πΌ0 = πΌ 26
and
We can extend the previous result by applying it on dense subspaces. This relaxes the assumption that
πΌπ‘ (β) β βπ‘
and simplies the verication
of local strict monotonicity since one can choose convenient spaces of test
Λ π‘ )0β€π‘β€π satisfying the same assump(β Λ π is a β₯ β
β₯ 1 -dense subspace of β. We β πΏ
functions. Consider a chain of spaces
(βπ‘ )0β€π‘β€π that (πΌπ‘ )0β€π‘β€π
tions as say
and such that
π«
πΏ1π« -continuous if ( ) ( ) πΌπ‘ : β, β₯ β
β₯πΏ1 β πΏ1π« (β±π‘β ), β₯ β
β₯πΏ1 is
π«
π«
is continuous for every π‘. We remark that the motivating example
(β°π‘β ) from
Assumption 4.1 satises this property (it is even Lipschitz continuous).
Corollary 5.4. Let πΌ0 be (βΛ π‘ )-locally strictly monotone. Then there exists at most one extension of πΌ0 to an πΏ1π« -continuous family (πΌπ‘ )0β€π‘β€π on Λ π‘ )-positively homogeneous and satises πΌπ‘ (β Λπ ) β β Λ π‘ and β which is (β Λπ . πΌ0 β πΌπ‘ = πΌ0 on β Proof.
Λπ . πΌπ‘ (π) is uniquely determined for π β β Λ π β β is dense and πΌπ‘ is continuous, πΌπ‘ is also determined on β. Since β Proposition 5.3 shows that
πΌ0 (β
) = supπ βπ« πΈ π [ β
]
In our last result, we show that
is
(βπ‘ )-locally
strictly monotone in certain cases. The idea here is that we already have an
(πΌπ‘ ) (as in Assumption 4.1), whose uniqueness we try to establish. πΆπ (Ξ©) the set of bounded continuous functions on Ξ© and by β πΆπ (Ξ©π‘ ) the β±π‘ -measurable functions in πΆπ (Ξ©), or equivalently the bounded functions which are continuous with respect to β₯πβ₯π‘ := sup0β€π β€π‘ β£ππ β£. Similarly, UCπ (Ξ©) and UCπ (Ξ©π‘ ) denote the sets of bounded uniformly continuous 1 1 β functions. We also dene ππ,π« to be the closure of πΆπ (Ξ©) in πΏπ« , while ππ,π« 1 β β denotes the π« -q.s. bounded elements of ππ,π« . Finally, ππ,π« (β±π‘ ) is obtained β β similarly from πΆπ (Ξ©π‘ ), while ππ’π,π« (β±π‘ ) is the space obtained when starting from UCπ (Ξ©π‘ ) instead of πΆπ (Ξ©π‘ ). extension
We denote by
Proposition 5.5. Let πΌ0 (β
) = supπ βπ« πΈ π [ β
]. Then strictly monotone for each of the cases (i) βπ‘ = πΆπ (Ξ©π‘ ), (ii) βπ‘ = UCπ (Ξ©π‘ ), β (iii) βπ‘ = πβ π,π« (β±π‘ ), β (iv) βπ‘ = πβ π’π,π« (β±π‘ ).
πΌ0
is (βπ‘ )-locally
Together with Corollary 5.4, this yields a uniqueness result for extensions. Before giving the proof, we indicate some examples covered by this result;
(πΌπ‘ ) is β = π1π’π,π« in both cases. (This 1 1 that ππ’π,π« = ππ,π« when π« is tight; cf. the
see also Example 2.1. The domain of statement implicitly uses the fact proof of [23, Proposition 5.2].)
27
(a) Let
(πΌπ‘ )
be the
lary 5.4 applies: if
Λπ ) β β Λπ‘ πΌπ‘ (β
Λπ‘ β
πΊ-expectation
as introduced in [27, 28]. Then Corol-
is any of the spaces in (i)(iv), the invariance property
Λπ β
is satised and
is dense in
β.
(b) Using the construction given in [23], the
πΊ-expectation
can be ex-
tended to the case when there is no nite upper bound for the volatility. This
πΊ (and then π« need not be tight). Λ π‘ = UCπ (Ξ©π‘ ) since πΌπ‘ (β Λπ ) β β Λ π‘ is satised β β β [23, Corollary 3.6], or also with βπ‘ = ππ’π,π« (β±π‘ ).
corresponds to a possibly innite function Here Corollary 5.4 applies with by the remark stated after
Proof of Proposition 5.5.
π‘ β [0, π ]. All topological notions in this proof β² β² are expressed with respect to π(π, π ) := β₯π β π β₯π‘ . Let π, π β βπ‘ be such that π β₯ π π« -q.s. and πβ (π > π ) > 0 for some πβ β π« . By translating and multiplying with positive constants, we may assume that 1 β₯ π β₯ π β₯ 0. Fix
We prove the cases (i)(iv) separately. (i) Choose
πΏ>0
small enough so that
π΄1 := {π β₯ π + 2πΏ}, Then
π΄1
and
π΄2
π΄1 .
0β€π β€1
(5.1)
as well as
π =0
on
π΄2
and
It remains to check that
πΌ0 (ππ ) > πΌ0 (π π ), If
π΄2 := {π β€ π + πΏ}.
π(π, π΄2 ) π(π, π΄1 ) + π(π, π΄2 )
is a continuous function satisfying on
and let
are disjoint closed sets and
π (π) :=
π =1
πβ {π β₯ π + 2πΏ} > 0
πΌ0 (π π ) = 0,
sup πΈ π [ππ ] > sup πΈ π [π π ].
i.e.,
π βπ«
the observation that
π βπ«
πΌ0 (ππ ) β₯ πΈ πβ [ππ ] β₯ 2πΏπβ (π΄1 ) > 0
already yields the proof.
πΌ0 (π π ) > 0. For π > 0, let ππ β π« be π ] β₯ πΌ0 (π π ) β π. Since π > π + πΏ on {π > 0} and since have ππ β₯ (π + πΏ)π β₯ (π + πΏπ )π and therefore
Hence, we may assume that
π such that πΈ π [π
0 β€ π β€ 1,
we
πΌ0 (ππ ) β₯ lim sup πΈ ππ [(π + πΏπ )π ] πβ0
= lim sup (1 + πΏ)πΈ ππ [π π ] πβ0
= (1 + πΏ) πΌ0 (π π ). As
πΏ>0
and
πΌ0 (π π ) > 0,
this ends the proof of (i).
(ii) The proof for this case is the same; we merely have to check that the function
π
π := π β π is π are. Thus there exists π > 0 such that π(π, π β² ) β€ π. We observe that π(π΄1 , π΄2 ) β₯ π
dened in (5.1) is uniformly continuous. Indeed,
uniformly continuous since
β£π(π) β π(π β² )β£ < πΏ
π
whenever
and
and hence that the denominator in (5.1) is bounded away from zero. One then checks by direct calculation that
π
28
is Lipschitz continuous.
(iii) We recall that
β πβ π« (β±π‘ )
coincides with the set of bounded
π« -quasi
continuous functions (up to modication); cf. [10, Theorem 25]. That is, a bounded
β±π‘β -measurable
function
β
β πβ π« (β±π‘ ) if and only if for all π > 0 that π (Ξ) > 1 β π for all π β π« and
is in
Ξ β Ξ© such ββ£Ξ is continuous. For πΏ > 0 small enough, we have πβ ({π β₯ π + 2πΏ}) > 0. Then, we nd a closed set Ξ β Ξ© such that π and π are continuous on Ξ and there exists a closed set
such that the restriction
(1 + πΏ) πΌ0 (1Ξπ ) < πΏ 2 πΌ0 (1{πβ₯π +2πΏ}β©Ξ ).
can
(5.2)
Dene the disjoint closed sets
π΄1 := {π β₯ π + 2πΏ} β© Ξ, and let
π
π΄2 := {π β€ π + πΏ} β© Ξ,
be the continuous function (5.1). We distinguish two cases. Sup-
pose rst that
πΏπΌ0 (π π ) β€ (1 + πΏ) πΌ0 (1Ξπ );
then, using (5.2),
πΌ0 (ππ ) β₯ 2πΏπΌ0 (1π΄1 ) > (1 + πΏ)πΏ β1 πΌ0 (1Ξπ ) β₯ πΌ0 (π π ) and we are done. Otherwise, we have
πΏπΌ0 (π π ) > (1 + πΏ) πΌ0 (1Ξπ ).
Moreover,
πΌ0 (ππ 1Ξ ) β₯ (1 + πΏ)πΌ0 (π π 1Ξ ) can be shown as in (i); we simply replace π π 1Ξ in that argument. Using the subadditivity of πΌ0 , we deduce that
by
πΌ0 (ππ ) + (1 + πΏ) πΌ0 (π π 1Ξπ ) β₯ πΌ0 (ππ 1Ξ ) + (1 + πΏ) πΌ0 (π π 1Ξπ ) β₯ (1 + πΏ) πΌ0 (π π 1Ξ ) + (1 + πΏ) πΌ0 (π π 1Ξπ ) β₯ (1 + πΏ) πΌ0 (π π ) and hence
πΌ0 (ππ )βπΌ0 (π π ) β₯ πΏπΌ0 (π π )β(1+πΏ) πΌ0 (π π 1Ξπ ) β₯ πΏπΌ0 (π π )β(1+πΏ) πΌ0 (1Ξπ ). The right hand side is strictly positive by assumption. (iv) The proof is similar to the one for (iii): we use [23, Proposition 5.2] instead of [10, Theorem 25] to nd
Ξ,
and then the observation made in the
proof of (ii) shows that the resulting function
π
is uniformly continuous.
References [1] P. Artzner, F. Delbaen, J.-M. Eber, and D. Heath. Coherent measures of risk. Math. Finance, 9(3):203228, 1999. [2] M. Avellaneda, A. Levy, and A. ParΓ‘s. Pricing and hedging derivative securities in markets with uncertain volatilities. Appl. Math. Finance, 2(2):7388, 1995. [3] K. Bichteler. Stochastic integration and πΏπ -theory of semimartingales. Ann. Probab., 9(1):4989, 1981.
29
[4] J. Bion-Nadal and M. Kervarec. Dynamic risk measuring under model uncertainty: taking advantage of the hidden probability measure. Preprint arXiv:1012.5850v1. [5] J. Bion-Nadal and M. Kervarec. Risk measuring under model uncertainty. To
appear in Ann. Appl. Probab.
[6] P. Cheridito, H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and N. Victoir. Second-order backward stochastic dierential equations and fully nonlinear parabolic PDEs. Comm. Pure Appl. Math., 60(7):10811110, 2007. [7] F. Delbaen. The structure of m-stable sets and in particular of the set of risk neutral measures. In SΓ©minaire de ProbabilitΓ©s XXXIX, volume 1874 of Lecture Notes in Math., pages 215258, Springer, Berlin, 2006. [8] F. Delbaen and W. Schachermayer. The Mathematics of Arbitrage. Springer, Berlin, 2006. [9] C. Dellacherie and P. A. Meyer. Probabilities and Potential B. North Holland, Amsterdam, 1982. [10] L. Denis, M. Hu, and S. Peng. Function spaces and capacity related to a sublinear expectation: application to πΊ-Brownian motion paths. Potential Anal., 34(2):139161, 2011. [11] L. Denis and C. Martini. A theoretical framework for the pricing of contingent claims in the presence of model uncertainty. Ann. Appl. Probab., 16(2):827 852, 2006. [12] N. El Karoui. Les aspects probabilistes du contrΓ΄le stochastique. In Ecole d'Γ©tΓ© de probabilitΓ©es de Saint-Flour, volume 876 of Lecture Notes in Math., pages 73238, Springer, Berlin, 1981. [13] D. Fernholz and I. Karatzas. Optimal arbitrage under model uncertainty. Ann. Appl. Probab., 21(6):21912225, 2011. [14] H. FΓΆllmer and A. Schied. Robust preferences and convex measures of risk. In Advances in Finance and Stochastics, pages 3956, Springer, Berlin, 2002. [15] H. FΓΆllmer and A. Schied. Stochastic Finance: An Introduction in Discrete Time. W. de Gruyter, Berlin, 2nd edition, 2004. [16] Y. Hu and S. Peng. Some estimates for martingale representation under πΊexpectation. Preprint arXiv:1004.1098v1, 2010. [17] J. Jacod and M. Yor. Γtude des solutions extrΓ©males et reprΓ©sentation intΓ©grale des solutions pour certains problΓ¨mes de martingales. Z. Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie und Verw. Gebiete, 38(2):83125, 1977. [18] R. L. Karandikar. On pathwise stochastic integration. Stochastic Process. Appl., 57(1):1118, 1995. [19] N. El Karoui and M.-C. Quenez. Dynamic programming and pricing of contingent claims in an incomplete market. SIAM J. Control Optim., 33(1):2966, 1995. [20] X. Li and S. Peng. Stopping times and related ItΓ΄'s calculus with πΊ-Brownian motion. Stochastic Process. Appl., 121(7):14921508, 2011. [21] T. J. Lyons. Uncertain volatility and the risk-free synthesis of derivatives. Appl. Math. Finance, 2(2):117133, 1995. [22] J. Neveu. Discrete-Parameter Martingales. North-Holland, Amsterdam, 1975. [23] M. Nutz. Random πΊ-expectations. Preprint arXiv:1009.2168v1, 2010.
30
[24] M. Nutz. A quasi-sure approach to the control of non-Markovian stochastic dierential equations. Electron. J. Probab., 17(23):123, 2012. [25] M. Nutz. Pathwise construction of stochastic integrals. Preprint arXiv:1108.2981v1, 2011. [26] S. Peng. Nonlinear expectations and nonlinear Markov chains. Chinese Ann. Math. Ser. B, 26(2):159184, 2005. [27] S. Peng. πΊ-expectation, πΊ-Brownian motion and related stochastic calculus of ItΓ΄ type. In Stochastic Analysis and Applications, volume 2 of Abel Symp., pages 541567, Springer, Berlin, 2007. [28] S. Peng. Multi-dimensional πΊ-Brownian motion and related stochastic calculus under πΊ-expectation. Stochastic Process. Appl., 118(12):22232253, 2008. [29] S. Peng. Backward stochastic dierential equation, nonlinear expectation and their applications. In R. Bhatia, editor, Proceedings of the International Congress of Mathematicians 2010, Hyderabad, India, volume 1, pages 393432, World Scientic, Singapore, 2011. [30] S. Peng. Nonlinear expectations and stochastic calculus under uncertainty. Preprint arXiv:1002.4546v1, 2010. [31] H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and J. Zhang. Quasi-sure stochastic analysis through aggregation. Electron. J. Probab., 16:18441879, 2011. [32] H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and J. Zhang. Wellposedness of second order backward SDEs. To appear in Probab. Theory Related Fields. [33] H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and J. Zhang. Dual formulation of second order target problems. To appear in Ann. Appl. Probab., 2010. [34] H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and J. Zhang. Martingale representation theorem for the πΊ-expectation. Stochastic Process. Appl., 121(2):265287, 2011. [35] Y. Song. Some properties on πΊ-evaluation and its applications to πΊ-martingale decomposition. Sci. China Math., 54(2):287300, 2011. [36] D. Stroock and S. R. S. Varadhan. Multidimensional Diusion Processes. Springer, New York, 1979. [37] J. Xu and B. Zhang. Martingale characterization of πΊ-Brownian motion. Stochastic Process. Appl., 119(1):232248, 2009.
31